The Response of Real Exchange Rates to Various Economic Shocks

Substantial fluctuations in real exchange rates, i.e., deviations from purchasing power parity (PPP), which closely mirror movements in nominal rates, have been one of the most notable international economic events since the breakdown of the Bretton Woods system. Dornbusch's disequilibrium theory [9], which presumes different speeds of adjustment in assets and goods markets, offers an explanation for temporary deviations from PPP only. Models assuming PPP as a long-run relationship have not been successful in interpreting the movements of the real exchange rates. Although, studies conducted for countries experiencing high or hyper-inflation provide evidence favoring PPP [42; 30; 29], the empirical evidence on PPP for industrialized, low inflation countries is not generally favorable.1 This is consistent with the view that PPP may hold better in high-inflation countries where the disturbances to their economies are mostly monetary in origin [31, 123-24], but PPP may not hold well when the real disturbances, which change equilibrium relative prices, dominate. Statistical evidence indicates that the real exchange rates of many countries are likely to be nonstationary or have long memory. That is, changes in the real values of many currencies tend to persist for very long period of time. This persistence implies that fluctuations in the real exchange rates are largely due to long-lasting effect of real disturbances. After revealing that "PPP does not hold as a long-run concept" for several exchange rates, Flynn and Boucher [12, 121] suggest that "One possible explanation ... is that there are time-varying real factors that are omitted from the PPP relationship." There are several well-established reasons why the real exchange rates may change in response to real disturbances. In the first place, permanent exogenous shocks to the tradable sector of the economy call for changes in competitiveness. For instance, a rise in the real price of oil will worsen the balance of trade position of a net oil-importing country and, therefore, call for a real depreciation of the currency of the country in order to improve its competitive position [32]. Second, when countries are growing at different rates, "productivity bias" will typically result in

[1]  Charles I. Plosser,et al.  Stochastic Trends and Economic Fluctuations , 1987 .

[2]  A. Nakibullah Comovements of Budget Deficits, Exchange Rates, and Outputs of Traded and Non-traded Goods , 1993 .

[3]  James H. Stock,et al.  Asymptotic Properties of Least Squares Estimators of Cointegrating Vectors , 1987 .

[4]  P. Phillips,et al.  Testing the null hypothesis of stationarity against the alternative of a unit root: How sure are we that economic time series have a unit root? , 1992 .

[5]  Richard T. Baillie,et al.  Cointegration and models of exchange rate determination , 1987 .

[6]  C. Sims MACROECONOMICS AND REALITY , 1977 .

[7]  Chris Chatfield,et al.  Introduction to Statistical Time Series. , 1976 .

[8]  R. Mcnown,et al.  National price levels, purchasing power parity, and cointegration: a test of four high inflation economies , 1989 .

[9]  J. Stock,et al.  Testing for Common Trends , 1988 .

[10]  Michael Osterwald-Lenum A Note with Quantiles of the Asymptotic Distribution of the Maximum Likelihood Cointegration Rank Test Statistics , 1992 .

[11]  Sources of Fluctuations in Real and Nominal Exchange Rates , 1992 .

[12]  D. Dickey,et al.  Testing for unit roots in autoregressive-moving average models of unknown order , 1984 .

[13]  Su Zhou,et al.  Purchasing power parity in high-inflation countries: further evidence , 1994 .

[14]  S. Johansen STATISTICAL ANALYSIS OF COINTEGRATION VECTORS , 1988 .

[15]  P. Krugman Oil and the Dollar , 1980 .

[16]  M. Hutchison,et al.  U.S. budget deficits and the real value of the dollar , 1985 .

[17]  H. Yoshikawa On the Equilibrium Yen-Dollar Rate , 1990 .

[18]  R. Dornbusch Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics , 1976, Journal of Political Economy.

[19]  F. Diebold,et al.  Real Exchange Rates under the Gold Standard , 1991, Journal of Political Economy.

[20]  Peter C. B. Phillips,et al.  Optimal Inference in Cointegrated Systems , 1991 .

[21]  Janice L. Boucher,et al.  Tests of long-run Purchasing Power Parity using alternative methodologies , 1993 .

[22]  David Hsieh The determination of the real exchange rate: The productivity approach , 1982 .

[23]  Nelson C. Mark Real and nominal exchange rates in the long run , 1990 .

[24]  C. Granger,et al.  Co-integration and error correction: representation, estimation and testing , 1987 .

[25]  A. Layton,et al.  Co-integration as an empirical test of purchasing power parity , 1990 .

[26]  W. Fuller,et al.  LIKELIHOOD RATIO STATISTICS FOR AUTOREGRESSIVE TIME SERIES WITH A UNIT ROOT , 1981 .

[27]  Mark P. Taylor,et al.  An empirical examination of long-run purchasing power parity using cointegration techniques , 1988 .

[28]  Faik Koray,et al.  Government spending and the exchange rate , 1991 .

[29]  Yoonbai Kim,et al.  Purchasing Power Parity in the Long Run: A Cointegration Approach , 1990 .

[30]  Bela Balassa,et al.  The Purchasing-Power Parity Doctrine: A Reappraisal , 1964, Journal of Political Economy.

[31]  Grayham E. Mizon,et al.  Cointegration and Error Correction Mechanisms , 1989 .

[32]  S. Ouliaris,et al.  A Test of Long-Run Purchasing Power Parity Allowing for Structural Breaks , 1991 .

[33]  Mark P. Taylor,et al.  Long-run purchasing power parity in the 1920s , 1988 .

[34]  K. Ohno Testing purchasing power parity and the Dornbusch overshooting model with vector autoregression , 1989 .

[35]  Shaghil Ahmed Government spending, the balance of trade and the terms of trade in British history , 1987 .

[36]  Philippe Jorion,et al.  Purchasing Power Parity in the Long Run , 1990 .