From Fossil Fuels to Renewables: The Role of Electricity Storage

We analyze the role of electricity storage for technological innovations in electricity generation. We propose a directed technological change model of the electricity sector, where innovative firms develop better electricity storage solutions, which affect not only the relative competitiveness between renewable and nonrenewable electricity sources but also the ease with which they can be substituted. Using a global firm-level data set of electricity patents from 1963 to 2011, we empirically analyze the determinants of innovation in electricity generation, and the role of storage in directing innovation. Our results show that electricity storage increases innovation not only in renewables but also in conventional technologies. This implies that efforts to increase innovation in storage can benefit conventional, fossil fuel-fired electricity plants as well as increasing the use of renewable electricity.

[1]  Linh Pham,et al.  Do Fossil-Fuel Taxes Promote Innovation in Renewable Electricity Generation? , 2016 .

[2]  D. Acemoglu,et al.  Transition to Clean Technology , 2014, Journal of Political Economy.

[3]  P. Aghion,et al.  The Environment and Directed Technical Change , 2009, The American economic review.

[4]  A. Cameron,et al.  Count Panel Data , 2015 .

[5]  Gerald A. Carlino,et al.  Urban Density and the Rate of Invention , 2006 .

[6]  Raphael Calel,et al.  Environmental Policy and Directed Technological Change: Evidence from the European Carbon Market , 2012, Review of Economics and Statistics.

[7]  R. Feenstra,et al.  The Next Generation of the Penn World Table , 2013 .

[8]  A. Bovenberg,et al.  Transitional Impacts of Environmental Policy in an Endogenous Growth Model. , 1996 .

[9]  Z. Griliches,et al.  Econometric Models for Count Data with an Application to the Patents-R&D Relationship , 1984 .

[10]  J. Gans Innovation and Climate Change Policy , 2011 .

[11]  R. Blundell,et al.  Dynamic Count Data Models of Technological Innovation , 1994 .

[12]  Ufuk Akcigit,et al.  Innovation, Reallocation and Growth , 2013, American Economic Review.

[13]  Per Krusell,et al.  Energy-Saving Technical Change , 2012 .

[14]  David Popp,et al.  Lessons from Patents: Using Patents to Measure Technological Change in Environmental Models , 2003 .

[15]  Bronwyn H Hall,et al.  Market value and patent citations , 2005 .

[16]  P. Aghion,et al.  Carbon Taxes, Path Dependency, and Directed Technical Change: Evidence from the Auto Industry , 2012, Journal of Political Economy.

[17]  P. Joskow Comparing the Costs of Intermittent and Dispatchable Electricity Generating Technologies , 2011 .

[18]  Richard Blundell,et al.  Individual effects and dynamics in count data models , 2002 .

[19]  David Popp,et al.  Entice: Endogenous Technological Change in the Dice Model of Global Warming , 2003 .

[20]  Patrick Schulte,et al.  Substitution between Clean and Dirty Energy Inputs: A Macroeconomic Perspective , 2017, Review of Economics and Statistics.

[21]  Bob van der Zwaan,et al.  A Sensitivity Analysis of Timing and Costs of Greenhouse Gas Emission Reductions , 2004 .

[22]  Z. Griliches,et al.  Econometric Models for Count Data with an Application to the Patents-R&D Relationship , 1984 .

[23]  Catalina Martínez,et al.  Insight into Different Types of Patent Families , 2010 .

[24]  Francesco Vona,et al.  Environmental policies, competition and innovation in renewable energy , 2014 .

[25]  Tony Lancaster,et al.  Orthogonal Parameters and Panel Data , 2002 .

[26]  Pravin K. Trivedi,et al.  Regression Analysis of Count Data , 1998 .

[27]  Stephen H. Schneider,et al.  Induced technological change and the attractiveness of CO2 abatement policies , 1999 .

[28]  David Popp,et al.  Entice-Br: The Effects of Backstop Technology R&D on Climate Policy Models , 2004 .

[29]  M. Glachant,et al.  Does Foreign Environmental Policy Influence Domestic Innovation? Evidence from the Wind Industry , 2014 .

[30]  D. Popp,et al.  Renewable Energy Policies and Technological Innovation: Evidence Based on Patent Counts , 2008 .

[31]  S. B. Thompson Simple Formulas for Standard Errors that Cluster by Both Firm and Time , 2009 .

[32]  Elena Verdolini,et al.  Efficiency Improving Fossil Fuel Technologies for Electricity Generation: Data Selection and Trends , 2011 .

[33]  G. King,et al.  A Seemingly Unrelated Poisson Regression Model , 1989 .

[34]  J. Noailly,et al.  Directing Technical Change from Fossil Fuel to Renewable Energy Innovation: An Application Using Firm Level Patent Data , 2014 .

[35]  Marzio Galeotti,et al.  Endogenous Induced Technical Change and the Costs of Kyoto , 2001 .

[36]  D. Acemoglu Directed Technical Change , 2001 .

[37]  Joëlle Noailly,et al.  Directing technical change from fossil-fuel to renewable energy innovation: An application using firm-level patent data , 2015 .

[38]  J. A. Smulders,et al.  Environmental quality and pollution-augmenting technological change in a two-sector endogenous growth model , 1995 .

[39]  Hélène Dernis,et al.  Triadic Patent Families Methodology , 2004 .

[40]  W. Greene,et al.  Accounting for Excess Zeros and Sample Selection in Poisson and Negative Binomial Regression Models , 1994 .

[41]  David Popp,et al.  Induced Innovation and Energy Prices , 2001 .

[42]  Linh Pham,et al.  Can Capital-Energy Substitution Foster Economic Growth? , 2016, Land Economics.

[43]  David Popp,et al.  Innovation in climate policy models: Implementing lessons from the economics of R&D , 2006 .

[44]  R. Blundell,et al.  Market share, market value and innovation in a panel of British manufacturing firms , 1999 .