Repeated games with asynchronous monitoring of an imperfect signal

We consider a long-run player facing a sequence of short-run opponents who receive noisy signals of the long-run player’s past actions. We modify the standard, synchronous-action, model by supposing that players observe an underlying public signal of the opponent’s actions at random and privately known times. In one modification, the public signals are Poisson events and either the observations occur within a small epsilon time interval or the observations have exponential waiting times. In the second modification, the underlying signal is the position of a diffusion process. We show that in the Poisson cases the high-frequency limit is the same as in the Fudenberg and Levine (2007, 2009) study of limits of high-frequency public signals, but that the limits can differ when the signals correspond to adiffusion.

[1]  B. Klein,et al.  The Role of Market Forces in Assuring Contractual Performance , 1981, Journal of Political Economy.

[2]  Johannes Hörner,et al.  The folk theorem for games with private almost-perfect monitoring , 2005 .

[3]  D. Monderer,et al.  Approximating common knowledge with common beliefs , 1989 .

[4]  Johannes Hörner,et al.  How Robust is the Folk Theorem , 2009 .

[5]  Andrzej Skrzypacz,et al.  THE ROLE OF INFORMATION IN REPEATED GAMES WITH FREQUENT ACTIONS , 2010 .

[6]  D. Fudenberg,et al.  Repeated Games with Frequent Signals , 2009 .

[7]  Roger Lagunoff,et al.  Asynchronous Choice in Repeated Coordination Games , 1997 .

[8]  Ariel T. Burstein,et al.  Foreign Know-How, Firm Control, and the Income of Developing Countries , 2007 .

[9]  Yuichi Yamamoto,et al.  A limit characterization of belief-free equilibrium payoffs in repeated games , 2009, J. Econ. Theory.

[10]  Andrzej Skrzypacz,et al.  THE ROLE OF INFORMATION IN REPEATED GAMES WITH FREQUENT ACTIONS , 2010 .

[11]  Michihiro Kandori,et al.  Introduction to Repeated Games with Private Monitoring , 2002, J. Econ. Theory.

[12]  E. Stacchetti,et al.  Towards a Theory of Discounted Repeated Games with Imperfect Monitoring , 1990 .

[13]  Nicolas Vieille,et al.  Recursive Methods in Discounted Stochastic Games: An Algorithm for delta Approaching 1 and a Folk Theorem , 2010 .

[14]  L. Shapley,et al.  Stochastic Games* , 1953, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[15]  Johannes Horner,et al.  Recursive Methods in Discounted Stochastic Games: An Algorithm for δ → 1 and a Folk Theorem , 2010 .

[16]  Drew Fudenberg,et al.  The Folk Theorem for Irreducible Stochastic Games with Imperfect Public Monitoring , 2010, J. Econ. Theory.

[17]  Lones Smith,et al.  THE FOLK THEOREM FOR REPEATED GAMES: A NEU CONDITION' , 1994 .

[18]  Drew Fudenberg,et al.  The Folk Theorem in Repeated Games with Discounting or with Incomplete Information , 1986 .

[19]  David Pearce,et al.  Information and timing in repeated partnerships , 1991 .

[20]  Stephen Morris,et al.  Repeated Games with Almost-Public Monitoring , 2002, J. Econ. Theory.

[21]  Satoru Takahashi,et al.  Coordination failure in repeated games with private monitoring , 2013, J. Econ. Theory.

[22]  Drew Fudenberg,et al.  Continuous time limits of repeated games with imperfect public monitoring , 2007 .

[23]  George J. Mailath,et al.  Folk Theorems with Bounded Recall Under (Almost) Perfect Monitoring , 2008, Games Econ. Behav..

[24]  D. Fudenberg,et al.  Efficiency and Observability with Long-Run and Short-Run Players , 1994 .

[25]  D. Fudenberg,et al.  Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with Funding from Working Paper Department of Economics the Folk Theorem with Imperfect Public Information , 2022 .

[26]  P. Dutta A Folk Theorem for Stochastic Games , 1995 .

[27]  Lones Smith,et al.  FOLK THEOREMS FOR REPEATED GAMES: a NEU Condition , 2011 .

[28]  Drew Fudenberg,et al.  Repeated Games with Long-run and Short-run Players , 1990 .

[29]  Jeffrey C. Ely,et al.  Belief-free Equilibria in Repeated Games , 2005 .