Status Competition and Performance in Work Groups

Status involves group members evaluating themselves relative to fellow group members according to some shared standard of value. Status has been described in economics, sociology and evolutionary anthropology. Based on this work, we treat status and the associated recognition by others as an intrinsic preference of all group members. There is disagreement about whether status competition enhances group performance by pushing group members to work harder, or whether it retards performance by causing unproductive behavior. We build a dynamic simulation model of a work group, where members are paid a bonus based on group performance. In addition to compensation, group members value a high status relative to their peers. Status is influenced both by contribution to group output and by non-productive, social activities of status enhancement. Group members allocate their total time between working and non-productive status enhancement, trying to maximize the combined utility from compensation and status rank. We show that status competition can serve to push group members to work hard and perform, provided that it is mainly based on merit. However, if status is also based on political maneuvering, status competition can lead to low group performance, especially in larger groups. Moreover, group performance may fluctuate and be unstable over time if the result of effort is noisy or if the group does not allow the sharing of ranks. The susceptibility to fluctuation depends on how status is awarded and updated over time. Thus, although a firm may not be able to avoid status competition, it may succeed in influencing its effects indirectly. We demonstrate these results analytically and via simulation.

[1]  H. Simon,et al.  A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice , 1955 .

[2]  P. Blau Exchange and Power in Social Life , 1964 .

[3]  R. Radner,et al.  Economic theory of teams , 1972 .

[4]  Jerome H. Barkow Strategies for Self-esteem and Prestige in Maradi, Niger Republic , 1975 .

[5]  M. Redman The economic approach to human behavior : . Chicago, Illinois: The University of Chicago Press, 1977. Pp. 314, $17.00 , 1978 .

[6]  T. Schelling Micromotives and Macrobehavior , 1978 .

[7]  E. Lazear,et al.  Rank-Order Tournaments as Optimum Labor Contracts , 1979, Journal of Political Economy.

[8]  Robert H. Frank,et al.  Interdependent Preferences and the Competitive Wage Structure , 1984 .

[9]  R. Frank Choosing the Right Pond: Human Behavior and the Quest for Status , 1986 .

[10]  R. Frank If Homo Economicus Could Choose His Own Utility Function, Would He Want One with a Conscience? Reply , 1987 .

[11]  R. Frank Passions Within Reason: The Strategic Role of the Emotions , 1990 .

[12]  Choosing the right pond: Human behavior and the quest for status , 1988 .

[13]  C. Ridgeway,et al.  Dominance and collective hierarchy formation in male and female task groups. , 1989 .

[14]  H. Hollander A Social Exchange Approach to Voluntary Cooperation , 1990 .

[15]  H. Simon,et al.  A mechanism for social selection and successful altruism. , 1990, Science.

[16]  J. Barkow Beneath new culture is old psychology: Gossip and social stratification. , 1992 .

[17]  E. Lazear,et al.  Peer Pressure and Partnerships , 1992, Journal of Political Economy.

[18]  J. Pfeffer Competitive Advantage Through People , 1994 .

[19]  B. Huberman,et al.  THE DYNAMICS OF SOCIAL DILEMMAS , 1994 .

[20]  Werner Güth,et al.  Is altruism evolutionarily stable , 1998 .

[21]  K. Sterelny The adapted mind , 1995 .

[22]  Christoph H. Loch,et al.  Collaboration, motivation, and the size of organizations , 1996, J. Organ. Comput. Electron. Commer..

[23]  W. E. Watkins,et al.  Information processing and organizational structure , 1998 .

[24]  N. Nicholson How hardwired is human behavior? , 1998, Harvard Business Review.

[25]  Gary E. Bolton,et al.  ERC: A Theory of Equity, Reciprocity, and Competition , 2000 .

[26]  P. Salus The Cathedral and the Bazaar , 2000 .