Why are Put Options so Expensive?

This paper studies the "overpriced puts puzzle" — the finding that historical prices of the S&P 500 put options have been too high and incompatible with the canonical asset-pricing models. To investigate whether put returns could be rationalized by another, possibly non-standard equilibrium model, we implement the model-free methodology of Bondarenko [2003a, Statistical Arbitrage and Securities Prices, Review of Financial Studies 16, 875–919]. The methodology requires no parametric assumptions on investors' preferences. Furthermore, it can be applied even when the sample is affected by certain selection biases (such as the Peso problem) and when investors' beliefs are incorrect. The main finding of the paper is that no model within a studied class of models can possibly explain the put anomaly.

[1]  Andrew B. Abel,et al.  Asset Prices Under Habit Formation and Catching Up with the Joneses , 1990 .

[2]  P. Bossaerts LEARNING-INDUCED SECURITIES PRICE VOLATILITY , 2000 .

[3]  Peter Bossaerts,et al.  Expectations and learning in Iowa , 2000 .

[4]  Alessio Saretto,et al.  Option Strategies: Good Deals and Margin Calls , 2006 .

[5]  S. Ross Options and Efficiency , 1976 .

[6]  Yacine Aït-Sahalia,et al.  Do option markets correctly price the probabilities of movement of the underlying asset , 2001 .

[7]  J. Harrison,et al.  Martingales and stochastic integrals in the theory of continuous trading , 1981 .

[8]  Francesca Cornelli,et al.  Stage Financing and the Role of Convertible Securities , 2003 .

[9]  Oleg Bondarenko Statistical Arbitrage and Securities Prices , 2002 .

[10]  G. Constantinides,et al.  Stochastic Dominance Bounds on Derivative Prices in a Multiperiod Economy with Proportional Transaction Costs , 2000 .

[11]  Tyler Shumway,et al.  Expected Option Returns , 2000 .

[12]  Jens Carsten Jackwerth,et al.  Option Implied Risk-Neutral Distributions and Implied Binomial Trees: A Literature Review , 1999 .

[13]  Ravi Jagannathan,et al.  Implications of Security Market Data for Models of Dynamic Economies , 1990, Journal of Political Economy.

[14]  Lars Peter Hansen,et al.  THE ROLE OF CONDITIONING INFORMATION IN DEDUCING TESTABLE RESTRICTIONS IMPLIED BY DYNAMIC ASSET PRICING MODELS1 , 1987 .

[15]  Peter Bossaerts,et al.  IPO Post-Issue Markets: Questionable Predilections But Diligent Learners? , 2001, Review of Economics and Statistics.

[16]  Vasant Naik,et al.  General Equilibrium Pricing of Options on the Market Portfolio with Discontinuous Returns , 1990 .

[17]  C. S. Jones A Nonlinear Factor Analysis of S&P 500 Index Option Returns , 2001 .

[18]  R. Bliss,et al.  Option-Implied Risk Aversion Estimates , 2004 .

[19]  S. Heston A Closed-Form Solution for Options with Stochastic Volatility with Applications to Bond and Currency Options , 1993 .

[20]  J. Campbell,et al.  By Force of Habit: A Consumption‐Based Explanation of Aggregate Stock Market Behavior , 1995, Journal of Political Economy.

[21]  Merton H. Miller,et al.  Prices for State-contingent Claims: Some Estimates and Applications , 1978 .

[22]  Gurdip Bakshi,et al.  Delta-Hedged Gains and the Negative Market Volatility Risk Premium , 2001 .

[23]  Jeff Fleming,et al.  Implied volatility functions: empirical tests , 1996, IEEE/IAFE 1996 Conference on Computational Intelligence for Financial Engineering (CIFEr).

[24]  A. Lo,et al.  Nonparametric Risk Management and Implied Risk Aversion , 2000 .

[25]  Larry G. Epstein,et al.  Substitution, Risk Aversion, and the Temporal Behavior of Consumption and Asset Returns: An Empirical Analysis , 1991, Journal of Political Economy.

[26]  L. Pedersen,et al.  Demand-Based Option Pricing , 2005 .

[27]  Alan G. White,et al.  The Pricing of Options on Assets with Stochastic Volatilities , 1987 .

[28]  Oleg Bondarenko Estimation of Risk-Neutral Densities Using Positive Convolution Approximation , 2002 .

[29]  Mark Rubinstein,et al.  The Valuation of Uncertain Income Streams and the Pricing of Options , 1976 .

[30]  G. Barone-Adesi,et al.  Efficient Analytic Approximation of American Option Values , 1987 .

[31]  R. Engle,et al.  Empirical Pricing Kernels , 1999 .

[32]  P. Bossaerts Filtering returns for unspecified biases in priors when testing asset pricing theory , 2004 .

[33]  Avi Bick On Viable Diffusion Price Processes of the Market Portfolio , 1990 .

[34]  Nicolas P. B. Bollen,et al.  Does Net Buying Pressure Affect the Shape of Implied Volatility Functions? , 2002 .

[35]  Larry G. Epstein,et al.  Substitution, Risk Aversion, and the Temporal Behavior of Consumption and Asset Returns: A Theoretical Framework , 1989 .

[36]  Recovering Risk-Neutral Densities: A New Nonparametric Approach , 2000 .

[37]  F. Modigliani,et al.  Risk-Adjusted Performance , 1997 .

[38]  R. Whaley Valuation of American Futures Options: Theory and Empirical Tests , 1986 .

[39]  Michael J. Brennan,et al.  The Pricing of Contingent Claims in Discrete Time Models , 1979 .

[40]  E. Ghysels,et al.  A study towards a unified approach to the joint estimation of objective and risk neutral measures for the purpose of options valuation , 2000 .

[41]  J. Jackwerth Recovering Risk Aversion from Option Prices and Realized Returns , 1998 .

[42]  David S. Bates Post-'87 crash fears in the S&P 500 futures option market , 2000 .

[43]  Hayne E. Leland,et al.  On Equilibrium Asset Price Processes , 1993 .

[44]  R. C. Merton,et al.  On Estimating the Expected Return on the Market: An Exploratory Investigation , 1980 .

[45]  António Câmara,et al.  A Generalization of the Brennan-Rubinstein Approach for the Pricing of Derivatives , 2003 .

[46]  Douglas T. Breeden,et al.  Prices of State-Contingent Claims Implicit in Option Prices , 1978 .

[47]  David M. Kreps,et al.  Martingales and arbitrage in multiperiod securities markets , 1979 .