The Dynamic Effects of Neutral and Investment‐Specific Technology Shocks

The neoclassical growth model is used to identify the short‐run effects of neutral technology shocks, which affect the production of all goods homogeneously, and investment‐specific shocks, which affect only investment goods. The real equipment price, crucial for identifying the investment shocks, experiences an abrupt increase in its average rate of decline in 1982, so the analysis is based on a split sample. On the basis of the preferred specification, the two technology shocks account for 73 percent of hours’ and 44 percent of output’s business cycle variation before 1982, and 38 percent and 80 percent afterward. The shocks also account for more than 40 percent of hours’ and 58 percent of output’s forecast errors over a three‐ to eight‐year horizon in both samples. The majority of these effects are driven by the investment shocks.

[1]  Robert J. Vigfusson,et al.  Assessing Structural Vars , 2006 .

[2]  Giorgio E. Primiceri,et al.  The Time Varying Volatility of Macroeconomic Fluctuations , 2006 .

[3]  F. Álvarez,et al.  Using Asset Prices to Measure the Persistence of the Marginal Utility of Wealth , 2005 .

[4]  Lawrence J. Christiano,et al.  Assessing the Usefulness of Structural Vector Autoregressions , 2005 .

[5]  L. Guerrieri,et al.  Can Long-Run Restrictions Identify Technology Shocks? , 2004 .

[6]  E. Sterken,et al.  Monetary Policy Rules From , 2004 .

[7]  Lawrence J. Christiano,et al.  Stock Market and Investment Goods Prices: Implications for Macroeconomics , 2003 .

[8]  P. Beaudry,et al.  Stock Prices, News and Economic Fluctuations , 2003 .

[9]  Lucy P. Eldridge,et al.  Alternative Hours Data and Their Impact on Productivity Change , 2003 .

[10]  James H. Stock,et al.  Has the Business Cycle Changed? Evidence and Explanations , 2003 .

[11]  Jonas D. M. Fisher Technology Shocks Matter , 2002 .

[12]  G. Violante,et al.  Investment-Specific Technical Change in the Us (1947-2000): Measurement and Macroeconomic Consequences , 2002 .

[13]  R. Hubbard,et al.  Tax Policy and Business Investment , 2002 .

[14]  Brent R. Moulton The Expanding Role of Hedonic Methods in the Official Statistics of the United States , 2001 .

[15]  Michele Boldrin,et al.  Habit Persistence, Asset Returns, and the Business Cycle , 2001 .

[16]  Per Krusell,et al.  The Role of Investment-Specific Technological Change in the Business Cycle , 2000 .

[17]  Lutz Kilian,et al.  Finite-Sample Properties of Percentile and Percentile-t Bootstrap Confidence Intervals for Impulse Responses , 1999, Review of Economics and Statistics.

[18]  Susanto Basu,et al.  Why is Productivity Procyclical? Why Do We Care? , 1999 .

[19]  John B. Taylor Monetary Policy Rules , 1999 .

[20]  Susanto Basu,et al.  Are Technology Improvements Contractionary? , 1998 .

[21]  J. Galí,et al.  Monetary Policy Rules and Macroeconomic Stability: Evidence and Some Theory , 1998 .

[22]  Thomas F. Cooley,et al.  Business cycle analysis without much theory A look at structural VARs , 1998 .

[23]  P. Perron,et al.  Computation and Analysis of Multiple Structural-Change Models , 1998 .

[24]  Michael Gort,et al.  Measuring the Rate of Technological Progress in Structures , 1998 .

[25]  John G. Fernald,et al.  Aggregate Productivity and Aggregate Technology , 1997 .

[26]  Jonas D. M. Fisher Relative prices, complementarities and comovement among components of aggregate expenditures , 1997 .

[27]  Jeffrey R. Campbell Entry, Exit, Embodied Technology, and Business Cycles , 1997 .

[28]  E. Mammen The Bootstrap and Edgeworth Expansion , 1997 .

[29]  J. Galí,et al.  Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations , 1996 .

[30]  V. Ramey [Can Technology Improvements Cause Productivity Slowdowns?]: Comment , 1996, NBER Macroeconomics Annual.

[31]  Per Krusell,et al.  Can Technology Improvements Cause Productivity Slowdowns? , 1996, NBER Macroeconomics Annual.

[32]  P. Perron,et al.  Estimating and testing linear models with multiple structural changes , 1995 .

[33]  Per Krusell,et al.  Long-Run Implications of Investment-Specific Technological Change , 1995 .

[34]  K. Hoover,et al.  Post hoc ergo propter once more an evaluation of 'does monetary policy matter?' in the spirit of James Tobin , 1994 .

[35]  C. Evans Productivity shocks and real business cycles , 1992 .

[36]  Robert J. Gordon,et al.  The measurement of durable goods prices , 1991 .

[37]  Olivier J. Blanchard,et al.  The Dynamic Effects of Aggregate Demand and Supply Disturbances , 1988 .

[38]  M. Watson,et al.  Sources of Business Cycle Fluctuations , 1988, NBER Macroeconomics Annual.

[39]  Jeremy Greenwood,et al.  Investment, Capacity Utilization and the Real Business Cycle , 1988 .

[40]  Charles I. Plosser,et al.  Stochastic Trends and Economic Fluctuations , 1987 .

[41]  E. Prescott Theory ahead of business-cycle measurement , 1986 .

[42]  S. Klepper,et al.  Time Paths in the Diffusion of Product Innovations , 1982 .

[43]  L. Hansen Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators , 1982 .

[44]  Roque B Fernandez,et al.  A Methodological Note on the Estimation of Time Series , 1981 .

[45]  G. Chow,et al.  Best Linear Unbiased Interpolation, Distribution, and Extrapolation of Time Series by Related Series , 1971 .

[46]  Frank T. Denton,et al.  Adjustment of Monthly or Quarterly Series to Annual Totals: An Approach Based on Quadratic Minimization , 1971 .