The 'Dutch disease': a disease after all?

Many third world oil producers are encountering serious problems in building up a diversified export base, while West European oil and gas producers (Netherlands, United Kingdom) are suffering a decline in their traded goods (manufacturing) sector induced by real wage pressures. It is becoming increasingly clear that high but temporary oil revenues may be somewhat ora mixed blessing, the quip of The Economist notwithstanding. The mechanism behind this unbalance is clear enough: part of the oil revenues is spent on non-traded goods which leads to a real appreciation (i.e., a rise in the relative price of non-traded goods in terms of traded goods). This in turn draws resources out of the non-oil traded sector into the non-traded goods producing sector (Corden and Neary (1982); van Wijnbergen (1980)). One may say that this is an efficient response to the increase in income from oil production, the United Kingdom (Mexico, Egypt, ...) simply should move into oil derived industries and non-traded goods and forget about their manufacturing sector until oil reserves are exhausted. However, many developing countries are hesitant to take this advice: after all the post-World War II success stories in economic development involve without exception countries that promoted their traded goods sector aggressively. Moreover, it is a well-established 'stylised fact' that technological progress is faster in the traded non-sheltered sectors of an economy than in the non-traded sector (Balassa (1964) is an early reference). Considering the hypothesis that technological progress, rather than taking place exogenously with the passage of time, is a function of accumulated experience, the concern of countries like Egypt, Mexico or Indonesia is much easier to understand. Since Solow (1957) and Denison (1962) it is known that capital accumulation explain only a small part of economic growth. If most of economic growth is caused by Learning by Doing induced technologica...

[1]  W. Max Corden,et al.  Booming Sector and De-Industrialisation in a Small Open Economy , 1982 .

[2]  G. Becker,et al.  Investment in Human Capital: A Theoretical Analysis , 1962, Journal of Political Economy.

[3]  Avinash Dixit,et al.  Theory Of International Trade , 1980 .

[4]  J. H. Levin,et al.  Economic interdependence and flexible exchange rates , 1985 .

[5]  M. Aoki,et al.  Oil export boom and Dutch-disease: A dynamic analysis , 1983 .

[6]  R. Dornbusch Real Interest Rates, Home Goods, and Optimal External Borrowing , 1981, Journal of Political Economy.

[7]  K. Dervis Policy analysis of shadow pricing, foreign borrowing, and resource extraction in Egypt , 1984 .

[8]  S. Wijnbergen Inflation, Employment, and the Dutch Disease in Oil-Exporting Countries: A Short-Run Disequilibrium Analysis , 1984 .

[9]  K. Arrow The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing , 1962 .

[10]  M. Selowsky,et al.  Energy prices, substitution, and optimal borrowing in the short run : an analysis of adjustment in oil - importing developing countries , 1984 .

[11]  Frank Hahn,et al.  The Theory of Economic Growth: A Survey , 1964 .

[12]  W. Buiter,et al.  Oil, Disinflation, and Export Competitiveness: A Model of the "Dutch Disease" , 1980 .

[13]  A. Razin The Terms of Trade and the Current Account: The Harberger-Laursen-Metzler Effect , 1983, Journal of Political Economy.

[14]  E. Mansfield Industrial research and technological innovation , 1968 .

[15]  Lars E. O. Svensson,et al.  Trade taxes and the current account , 1983 .

[16]  R. C. Merton On the Role of Social Security as a Means for Efficient Risk-Bearing in an Economy Where Human Capital is Not Tradeable , 1981 .

[17]  E. F. Denison,et al.  The Sources of Economic Growth in the United States , 1962 .