Modeling Regional Innovation and Competitiveness

The importance of science and technology to industrial development is unchallenged. What has occupied many researchers in the last half of the 20th century is trying to understand the process of technological progress and industrial development in order to better manage it. An early notion was that progress proceeded in a linear fashion, starting with scientific research producing fundamental knowledge, which then stimulated applied research and development (R&D). This R&D then led to marketable products, newer and better than the old ones. This simple idea has been set aside in favor of much more complicated systems with multiple feedback loops and interactions between technological, economic, social, and management systems. Firms are no longer regarded as independent or isolated actors, but are more properly seen as being parts of a system, linked together (technologically, economically, socially, and managerially) in groups or clusters.

[1]  Elise S. Brezis,et al.  Technology and the Life Cycle of Cities , 1993 .

[2]  E. Lorenz,et al.  Trust, Community and Cooperation: Toward a Theory of Industrial Districts , 1992 .

[3]  Strategies for New Technology: Case Studies from Britain and France , 1989 .

[4]  G. Grossman,et al.  Quality Ladders in the Theory of Growth , 1989 .

[5]  Rinaldo Evangelista,et al.  Embodied and disembodied innovative activities: evidence from the Italian innovation survey , 1996 .

[6]  Marcel Côte,et al.  Growing the next Silicon Valley , 1987 .

[7]  G. Fairtlough Innovation and Organization , 1995 .

[8]  Paul Israel,et al.  The Sources of Innovation , 1990 .

[9]  A. Chandler,et al.  Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition in Silicon Valley and Route 128 , 1994 .

[10]  Ulrich Hilpert,et al.  Regional innovation and decentralization : high tech industry and government policy , 1991 .

[11]  R. Nelson,et al.  National Innovation Systems , 1993 .

[12]  Multiple Linked "Diamonds" and the International Competitiveness of Export-Dependent Industries: The New Zealand Experience , 1993 .

[13]  R. Nelson National Innovation Systems: A Comparative Analysis , 1993 .

[14]  James M. Utterback,et al.  Innovation, Competition, and Industry Structure , 1993 .

[15]  Edward L. Glaeser,et al.  Geographic Concentration in U.S. Manufacturing Industries: A Dartboard Approach , 1994, Journal of Political Economy.

[16]  Huib Ernste,et al.  Regional development and contemporary industrial response: Extending flexible specialisation , 1992 .

[17]  Gilles Paquet,et al.  Evolutionary economics and the new international political economy , 1996 .

[18]  Andrew Tylecote Financial Systems and Innovation , 1995 .

[19]  M. Hobday Innovation in Semiconductor Technology: The Limits of the Silicon Valley Network Model , 1995 .

[20]  Joseph R. D’cruz,et al.  The "Double Diamond" Model of International Competitiveness: The Canadian Experience , 1993 .

[21]  Georg Angenendt Identification and Discussion of parameters that can be used to analyze industries with Michael E. Porter's system of determinants that influence the competitive position of nations' industries , 1994 .

[22]  M. Porter The Competitive Advantage Of Nations , 1990 .

[23]  Regional Economic Development: Essays in Honour of Francois Perroux , 1988 .

[24]  Kenichi Ohmae,et al.  End of the Nation State , 1995 .

[25]  Allen J. Scott,et al.  Pathways to Industrialization and Regional Development , 1995 .

[26]  Mark Dodgson,et al.  The Handbook of Industrial Innovation , 1994 .

[27]  Luc Soete,et al.  Technology, productivity, and job creation , 1996 .

[28]  Edward M. Bergman,et al.  Regions Reconsidered: Economic Networks, Innovation, and Local Development in Industrialized Countries , 1991 .

[29]  Donald J. Daly,et al.  Porter's Diamond and Exchange Rates , 1993 .

[30]  Gordon H. Hanson Localization Economies, Vertical Organization and Trade , 1994 .