Aggregate Comparative Statics

In aggregative games, each player's payoff depends on her own actions and an aggregate of the actions of all the players (for example, sum, product or some moment of the distribution of actions). Many common games in industrial organization, political economy, public economics, and macroeconomics can be cast as aggregative games. In most of these situations, the behavior of the aggregate is of interest both directly and also indirectly because the comparative statics of the actions of each player can be obtained as a function of the aggregate. In this paper, we provide a general and tractable framework for comparative static results in aggregative games. We focus on two classes of aggregative games: (1) aggregative of games with strategic substitutes and (2) "nice" aggregative games, where payoff functions are continuous and concave in own strategies. We provide simple sufficient conditions under which "positive shocks" to individual players increase their own actions and have monotone effects on the aggregate. We show how this framework can be applied to a variety of examples and how this enables more general and stronger comparative static results than typically obtained in the literature.

[1]  R. Hartley,et al.  Weak links, good shots and other public good games: Building on BBV , 2007 .

[2]  W. M. Gorman The Structure of Utility Functions , 1968 .

[3]  Avinash Dixit,et al.  Strategic Behavior in Contests , 1987 .

[4]  Peter A. Diamond,et al.  Aggregate Demand Management in Search Equilibrium , 1982, Journal of Political Economy.

[5]  W. Novshek On the Existence of Cournot Equilibrium , 1985 .

[6]  J. Miguel Villas-Boas,et al.  Comparative Statics of Fixed Points , 1997 .

[7]  Luis C. Corchón Comparative statics for aggregative games the strong concavity case , 1994 .

[8]  A. Tarski A LATTICE-THEORETICAL FIXPOINT THEOREM AND ITS APPLICATIONS , 1955 .

[9]  E. Kalai Large Robust Games , 2004 .

[10]  D. Hale Nonparametric Comparative Statics and Stability , 1999 .

[11]  Daron Acemoglu,et al.  Robust comparative statics in large static games , 2010, 49th IEEE Conference on Decision and Control (CDC).

[12]  Frank Hahn,et al.  The Stability of the Cournot Oligopoly Solution , 1962 .

[13]  Matthew J. Kotchen Equilibrium existence and uniqueness in impure public good models , 2007 .

[14]  R. Tollison,et al.  Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society , 1982 .

[15]  J. Milnor Topology from the differentiable viewpoint , 1965 .

[16]  Robert J. Plemmons,et al.  Nonnegative Matrices in the Mathematical Sciences , 1979, Classics in Applied Mathematics.

[17]  D. M. Topkis Equilibrium Points in Nonzero-Sum n-Person Submodular Games , 1979 .

[18]  X. Vives Innovation and Competitive Pressure , 2004 .

[19]  D. Acemoglu Equilibrium Bias of Technology , 2005 .

[20]  Burkhard C. Schipper Submodularity and the evolution of Walrasian behavior , 2004, Int. J. Game Theory.

[21]  Paul R. Milgrom,et al.  Rationalizability, Learning, and Equilibrium in Games with Strategic Complementarities , 1990 .

[22]  F. Szidarovszky,et al.  On the Existence and Uniqueness of Pure Nash Equilibrium in Rent-Seeking Games , 1997 .

[23]  Roger Hartley,et al.  The Geometry of Aggregative Games , 2005 .

[24]  Kofi O. Nti,et al.  Comparative Statics of Contests and Rent-Seeking Games , 1997 .

[25]  Efe A. Ok,et al.  Evolution of Interdependent Preferences in Aggregative Games , 2000, Games Econ. Behav..

[26]  X. Vives Nash equilibrium with strategic complementarities , 1990 .

[27]  Ana B. Ania,et al.  The evolutionary stability of perfectly competitive behavior , 2005 .

[28]  Jesús Seade,et al.  On the effects of entry , 1980 .

[29]  M. K. Jensen Aggregative games and best-reply potentials , 2010 .

[30]  Alex Possajennikov,et al.  Evolutionary foundations of aggregate-taking behavior , 2003 .

[31]  Raymond Deneckere,et al.  A generalized theorem of the maximum , 1993 .

[32]  S. Skaperdas Cooperation, Conflict, and Power in the Absence of Property Rights , 1991 .

[33]  Donald M. Topkis,et al.  Minimizing a Submodular Function on a Lattice , 1978, Oper. Res..

[34]  J. Hirshleifer Conflict and rent-seeking success functions: Ratio vs. difference models of relative success , 1989 .

[35]  Andrew John,et al.  Coordinating Coordination Failures in Keynesian Models , 1988 .

[36]  Tarun Sabarwal,et al.  Monotone Comparative Statics for Games with Strategic Substitutes , 2010 .

[37]  Richard Schmalensee,et al.  Output and Welfare Implications of Monopolistic Third-Degree Price Discrimination , 1980 .

[38]  O. Mangasarian PSEUDO-CONVEX FUNCTIONS , 1965 .

[39]  Fernando Vega Redondo,et al.  The evolution of walrasian behavior , 1996 .

[40]  R. Amir Cournot Oligopoly and the Theory of Supermodular Games , 1996 .

[41]  Pradeep Dubey,et al.  Strategic complements and substitutes, and potential games , 2006, Games Econ. Behav..

[42]  K. Vind,et al.  Independence, Additivity, Uncertainty , 2003 .

[43]  Paul R. Milgrom,et al.  Monotone Comparative Statics , 1994 .

[44]  Losser Alphonse,et al.  Selten (Reinhard) - Preispolitik der Mehrproduktenunternehmung in der statischen Theorie , 1970 .

[45]  Roger Hartley,et al.  Asymmetric contests with general technologies , 2005 .

[46]  Jonathan Weinstein,et al.  Sensitivity of equilibrium behavior to higher-order beliefs in nice games , 2011, Games Econ. Behav..

[47]  Glenn C. Loury,et al.  Market Structure and Innovation , 1979 .

[48]  G. Tullock Efficient Rent Seeking , 2001 .

[49]  John Maybee,et al.  Qualitative Economics and the Scope of the Correspondence Principle , 1968 .

[50]  Nikolai S. Kukushkin,et al.  A fixed-point theorem for decreasing mappings , 1994 .

[51]  H. Varian,et al.  On the private provision of public goods , 1986 .

[52]  X. Vives Oligopoly Pricing: Old Ideas and New Tools , 1999 .