Experience Benefits and Firm Organization

A principal requires a manager for production. He can use an internal manager, or contracts with an external manger. In each case, the manager obtains experience benefits from production. When the principal uses an internal manager, both parties share cost information. When the principal contracts with an external manager, only the external manager acquires cost information. The internal manager has limited access to the credit market; he has a minimum income constraint. The external manager has adequate access and has no minimum income constraint. The principal faces a tradeo. Hiring an internal manager eliminates asymmetric information, but extracting experience rent is more difficult due to the minimum income constraint. Hiring an external manager means giving up information rent, but extracting experience rent is feasible. Whether the principal uses an internal or an external manager depends on the tightness of the minimum income constraint and the magnitude of the experience benefit. The principal's optimal choice may not be socially efficient.

[1]  Jacques Crémer,et al.  Language and the Theory of the Firm , 2007 .

[2]  George G. Triantis,et al.  Economic and Legal Boundaries of Firms , 2006 .

[3]  J. Rosés Subcontracting and Vertical Integration in the Spanish Cotton Industry , 2005 .

[4]  Peter G. Klein,et al.  The Make-or-Buy Decision: Lessons from Empirical Studies , 2004 .

[5]  J. Laffont,et al.  The Theory of Incentives: The Principal-Agent Model , 2001 .

[6]  T. Hubbard Contractual form and market thickness in trucking , 2001 .

[7]  Alberto Fernández,et al.  Causes of Subcontracting: Evidence from Panel Data on Construction Firms , 2000 .

[8]  Anke S. Kessler,et al.  The Theory of Human Capital Revisited: On the Interaction of General and Specific Investments , 2000, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[9]  Christina L. Ahmadjian,et al.  Keiretsu, Governance, and Learning: Case Studies in Change from the Japanese Automotive Industry , 2000 .

[10]  T. Holmes Localization of Industry and Vertical Disintegration , 1999, Review of Economics and Statistics.

[11]  D. Acemoglu,et al.  The Structure of Wages and Investment in General Training , 1998, Journal of Political Economy.

[12]  Joseph G. Altonji,et al.  Do Wages Rise with Job Seniority? A Reassessment , 1997 .

[13]  Klaus M. Schmidt The Costs and Benefits of Privatization: An Incomplete Contracts Approach , 1996 .

[14]  Derek Neal,et al.  Industry-Specific Human Capital: Evidence from Displaced Workers , 1995, Journal of Labor Economics.

[15]  Jacques Crémer,et al.  Arm's Length Relationships , 1995 .

[16]  Stephen Craig Pirrong,et al.  Contracting Practices in Bulk Shipping Markets: A Transactions Cost Explanation , 1993, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[17]  S. Masten,et al.  Vertical integration in the U.S. auto industry: A note on the influence of transaction specific assets , 1989 .

[18]  Scott E. Masten,et al.  A Legal Basis for the Firm , 1988 .

[19]  Oliver E. Williamson The Economic Institutions of Capitalism , 1986, The Antitrust Bulletin.

[20]  O. Williamson,et al.  Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. , 1977 .

[21]  S. Rosen Learning by Experience as Joint Production , 1972 .

[22]  Y. Ben-Porath The Production of Human Capital and the Life Cycle of Earnings , 1967, Journal of Political Economy.

[23]  A Proposition , 1873, The Southern medical record.

[24]  Sanford J. Grossman,et al.  You have printed the following article : The Costs and Benefits of Ownership : A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration , 2007 .

[25]  Tracy R. Lewis,et al.  Technological Change and the Boundaries of the Firm , 1991 .

[26]  David B. Stern,et al.  Market failure in training? : new economic analysis and evidence on training of adult employees , 1991 .

[27]  Sherwin Rosen,et al.  Learning and Experience in the Labor Market , 1972 .