Jump Risks and the Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing Model

The specification of the stochastic process for stock prices is an important assumption underlying most equilibrium and option-pricing models in modern finance. This is particularly true of the continuous-time capital asset pricing models where it is assumed that asset prices follow diffusion processes with continuous sample paths (see Merton 1973a; Breeden 1979; Grossman and Shiller 1982). The extent to which the implications of these models generalize to discontinuous sample paths is an unanswered question in theoretical finance. However, the answer to this question is of more than just theoretical interest since accumulated empirical evidence appears to be inconsistent with the continuous sample path assumption (see Rosenberg 1972; Oldfield, Rogalski, and Jarrow 1977; Rosenfeld 1982). One purpose of this paper is to provide some answers to this question. We do this by extending Merton's (1973a) intertemporal asset pricing model, in the special case of a constant investment opportunity set, to include discontinuous sample paths for asset prices. The constant investment opportunity set assumption is imposed because we are interested in obtaining sufficient conditions under which an instantaneous capital asset pricing model (CAPM) results. The extension of our model to a stochastic opportunity set is discussed briefly in the text. This paper investigates an economy where stock prices follow a jump-diffusion process. The first part of the analysis derives a sufficient condition under which an instantaneous CAPM will characterize equilibrium expected returns. The sufficient condition is that the jump component of a stock's return must be "unsystematic" and diversifiable in the market portfolio. The second part of the paper is an empirical investigation of the satisfaction of this condition. The evidence is seen to be inconsistent with the satisfaction of this hypothesis, that is, the market portfolio appears to contain a jump component.

[1]  S. Dreyfus Dynamic Programming and the Calculus of Variations , 1960 .

[2]  E. Fama Multiperiod Consumption-Investment Decisions , 1970 .

[3]  R. C. Merton,et al.  Optimum consumption and portfolio rules in a continuous - time model Journal of Economic Theory 3 , 1971 .

[4]  M. C. Jensen Capital Markets: Theory and Evidence , 1972 .

[5]  Barr Rosenberg. The Behavior of Random Variables with Nonstationary Variance and the Distribution of Security Prices , 1972 .

[6]  R. C. Merton,et al.  AN INTERTEMPORAL CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL , 1973 .

[7]  E. Fama A NOTE ON THE MARKET MODEL AND THE TWO‐PARAMETER MODEL , 1973 .

[8]  Alan Kraus,et al.  MARKET EQUILIBRIUM IN A MULTIPERIOD STATE PREFERENCE MODEL WITH LOGARITHMIC UTILITY , 1975 .

[9]  R. C. Merton,et al.  Option pricing when underlying stock returns are discontinuous , 1976 .

[10]  S. Ross The arbitrage theory of capital asset pricing , 1976 .

[11]  Robert A. Jarrow,et al.  An autoregressive jump process for common stock returns , 1977 .

[12]  Stephen A. Ross,et al.  Mutual fund separation in financial theory—The separating distributions , 1978 .

[13]  Douglas T. Breeden An Intertemporal Asset Pricing Model with Stochastic Consumption and Investment Opportunities , 1979 .

[14]  E. Rosenfeld Stochastic processes of common stock returns : an empirical examination. , 1980 .

[15]  Consumption Correlatedness and Risk Measurement in Economies with Non trade Assets and Heterogeneous Information , 1982 .

[16]  S. Ross,et al.  A theory of the term structure of interest rates'', Econometrica 53, 385-407 , 1985 .