The value of innovation: The interaction of competition, R&D and IP

This paper analyses market valuations of UK companies using a new data set of their R&D and IP activities (1989–2002). In contrast to previous studies, the analysis is conducted at the sectoral-level, where the sectors are based on the technological classification originating from Pavitt [Pavitt, K., 1984. Sectoral patterns of technical change. Research Policy 13, 343–373]. The first main result is that the valuation of R&D varies substantially across these sectors. Another important result is that, on average, firms that receive only UK patents tend to have no significant market premium. In direct contrast, patenting through the European Patent Office does raise market value, as does the registration of trade marks in the UK for most sectors. To explore these variations the paper links competitive conditions with the market valuation of innovation. Using profit persistence as a measure of competitive pressure, we find that the sectors that are the most competitive have the lowest market valuation of R&D. Furthermore, within the most competitive sector (‘science based’ manufacturing), firms with larger market shares (an inverse indicator of competitive pressure) also have higher R&D valuations, as well as some positive return to UK patents. We conclude that this evidence supports Schumpeter by finding higher returns to innovation in less than fully competitive markets and contradicts Arrow [Arrow, K., 1962. Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In: Nelson, R. (Ed.), The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity. Princeton University Press, Princeton], who argued that, with the existence of IP rights, competitive market structure provides higher incentives to innovate.

[1]  C. F. Phillips Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance , 1971 .

[2]  S. Nickell Competition and Corporate Performance , 1996, Journal of Political Economy.

[3]  R. Blundell,et al.  Market share, market value and innovation in a panel of British manufacturing firms , 1999 .

[4]  Stephen W. Pruitt,et al.  A Simple Approximation of Tobin's Q , 1994 .

[5]  Bronwyn H Hall,et al.  Innovation and Market Value , 1998 .

[6]  Otto Toivanen,et al.  Innovation and the Market Value of UK Firms, 1989-1995 , 2002 .

[7]  K. Arrow Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention , 1962 .

[8]  F. Scherer,et al.  Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance. , 1971 .

[9]  Dietmar Harhoff,et al.  Uncertainty and the size distribution of rewards from innovation , 2000 .

[10]  Z. Griliches Market Value, R&D, and Patents , 1981 .

[11]  Dennis C. Mueller,et al.  The Dynamics of company profits : an international comparison , 1990 .

[12]  K. Pavitt Sectoral Patterns of Technical Change : Towards a Taxonomy and a Theory : Research Policy , 1984 .

[13]  Mary O'Mahony,et al.  Productivity, Innovation and Economic Performance , 2000 .

[14]  Sandro Mendonça,et al.  Trademarks as an Indicator of Innovation and Industrial Change , 2004 .

[15]  Daniel A. Levinthal,et al.  Innovation and Learning: The Two Faces of R&D , 1989 .

[16]  Jan Boone,et al.  Intensity of competition and the incentive to innovate , 2001 .

[17]  A. Jacquemin,et al.  The Persistence of Profits - a European Comparison , 1988 .

[18]  Dennis C. Mueller,et al.  The Dynamics of Company Profits , 2005 .

[19]  Paul Dewick,et al.  Technological change, industry structure and the environment , 2004 .

[20]  Harald Gruber,et al.  Competition and Innovation: The Diffusion of Mobile Telecommunications in Central and Eastern Europe , 2000, Inf. Econ. Policy.

[21]  J. Heckman Sample selection bias as a specification error , 1979 .

[22]  Intellectual property in UK firms: creating intangible assets and distributing the benefits via wages and jobs* , 2001 .

[23]  R. Gilbert,et al.  Competition and Innovation , 2006 .

[24]  D. Bosworth,et al.  Market Value, R&D and Intellectual Property: An Empirical Analysis of Large Australian Firms , 2001 .

[25]  P. Geroski The persistence of profits , 1986 .

[26]  Thomas C. Melvin,et al.  European Patent Office , 2002 .

[27]  A. Benito 'Oscillate Wildly': asymmetries and persistence in company-level profitability , 2001 .

[28]  R. Lambert,et al.  Lambert Review of Business-University Collaboration: Final Report , 2003 .

[29]  Glenn C. Loury,et al.  Market Structure and Innovation , 1979 .

[30]  Stephen Nickell,et al.  Competition and Crporate Performance , 1993 .

[31]  M. Nerlove,et al.  Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects , 1988 .

[32]  John Bessant,et al.  Managing Innovation: Integrating Technological, Market, and Organizational Change, 2nd Edition , 2001 .

[33]  Baruch Lev,et al.  Intangible Assets: Values, Measures, and Risks , 2003 .

[34]  G. Waring,et al.  Industry Differences in the Persistence of Firm-Specific Returns , 1996 .

[35]  Kevin Lee,et al.  Persistence of profitability and competition in emerging markets , 2001 .

[36]  R. W. Vossen R&D, firm size and branch of industry: policy implications , 1998 .

[37]  R. Mcgregor Who Owns Whom , 1993 .

[38]  Morton I. Kamien,et al.  On the Degree of Rivalry for Maximum Innovative Activity , 1976 .

[39]  C. Greenhalgh,et al.  Running to Stand Still? - Intellectual Property and Value Added in Innovating Firms , 2002 .

[40]  W. Baumol,et al.  Contestable Markets and the Theory of Industry Structure , 1982 .

[41]  Jerry A. Hausman,et al.  Errors in Variables in Panel Data , 1984 .