Managing uncertainty: information and insurance under the risk of starvation.

In an uncertain world, animals face both unexpected opportunities and danger. Such outcomes can select for two potential strategies: collecting information to reduce uncertainty, or insuring against it. We investigate the relative value of information and insurance (energy reserves) under starvation risk by offering model foragers a choice between constant and varying food sources over finite foraging bouts. We show that sampling the variable option (choosing it when it is not expected to be good) should decline both with lower reserves and late in foraging bouts; in order to be able to reap the reduction in uncertainty associated with exploiting a variable resource effectively, foragers must be able to afford and compensate for an initial increase in the risk of an energetic shortfall associated with choosing the option when it is bad. Consequently, expected exploitation of the varying option increases as it becomes less variable, and when the overall risk of energetic shortfall is reduced. In addition, little activity on the variable alternative is expected until reserves are built up early in a foraging bout. This indicates that gathering information is a luxury while insurance is a necessity, at least when foraging on stochastic and variable food under the risk of starvation.

[1]  C. Clark,et al.  Dynamic Modeling in Behavioral Ecology , 2019 .

[2]  C. Clark,et al.  Dynamic State Variable Models in Ecology: Methods and Applications , 2001 .

[3]  J. McNamara,et al.  Risk-Prone Behaviour Under Rules Which Have Evolved in a Changing Environment , 1996 .

[4]  Marc Mangel,et al.  Dynamic models in behavioural and evolutionary ecology , 1988, Nature.

[5]  I. Cuthill,et al.  The ecological costs of avian fat storage. , 1993, Philosophical transactions of the Royal Society of London. Series B, Biological sciences.

[6]  D. Wilson,et al.  Costs and limits of phenotypic plasticity. , 1998, Trends in ecology & evolution.

[7]  Sasha R. X. Dall,et al.  Interruptions to foraging and learning in a changing environment , 1999, Animal Behaviour.

[8]  J. Krebs,et al.  Learning and Foraging: Individuals, Groups, and Populations , 1992, The American Naturalist.

[9]  I. Cuthill,et al.  Managing time and energy , 1997 .

[10]  David Sloan Wilson,et al.  On the Coexistence of Specialists and Generalists , 1994, The American Naturalist.

[11]  T. DeWitt Costs and limits of phenotypic plasticity: Tests with predator‐induced morphology and life history in a freshwater snail , 1998 .

[12]  T. Valone,et al.  Potential disadvantages of using socially acquired information. , 2002, Philosophical transactions of the Royal Society of London. Series B, Biological sciences.

[13]  A. Houston,et al.  General results concerning the trade-off between gaining energy and avoiding predation , 1993 .

[14]  Thomas J Valone,et al.  Public information for the assessment of quality: a widespread social phenomenon. , 2002, Philosophical transactions of the Royal Society of London. Series B, Biological sciences.

[15]  D. Stephens Variance and the Value of Information , 1989, The American Naturalist.

[16]  A reevaluation of the logic of pilferage effects, predation risk, and environmental variability on avian energy regulation: the critical role of time budgets , 2001 .

[17]  Sasha R. X. Dall,et al.  The information costs of generalism , 1997 .

[18]  David W. Stephens,et al.  On economically tracking a variable environment , 1987 .

[19]  A. Houston,et al.  A framework for the functional analysis of behaviour , 1988, Behavioral and Brain Sciences.

[20]  R. Sibly,et al.  Producers and scroungers: A general model and its application to captive flocks of house sparrows , 1981, Animal Behaviour.

[21]  M. Mangel Dynamic information in uncertain and changing worlds. , 1990, Journal of theoretical biology.

[22]  Alasdair I. Houston,et al.  Models of Adaptive Behaviour: An Approach Based on State , 1999 .