Spatial reciprocity in the evolution of cooperation

Cooperation is key to the survival of all biological systems. The spatial structure of a system constrains who interacts with whom (interaction partner) and who acquires new traits from whom (role model). Understanding when and to what degree a spatial structure affects the evolution of cooperation is an important and challenging topic. Here, we provide an analytical formula to predict when natural selection favours cooperation where the effects of a spatial structure are described by a single parameter. We find that a spatial structure promotes cooperation (spatial reciprocity) when interaction partners overlap role models. When they do not, spatial structure inhibits cooperation even without cooperation dilemmas. Furthermore, a spatial structure in which individuals interact with their role models more often shows stronger reciprocity. Thus, imitating individuals with frequent interactions facilitates cooperation. Our findings are applicable to both pairwise and group interactions and show that strong social ties might hinder, while asymmetric spatial structures for interaction and trait dispersal could promote cooperation.

[1]  W. Hamilton,et al.  The evolution of cooperation. , 1984, Science.

[2]  M. Nowak,et al.  Evolutionary games and spatial chaos , 1992, Nature.

[3]  Duncan J. Watts,et al.  Collective dynamics of ‘small-world’ networks , 1998, Nature.

[4]  Albert,et al.  Emergence of scaling in random networks , 1999, Science.

[5]  Long Wang,et al.  Cooperation with both synergistic and local interactions can be worse than each alone , 2014, Scientific Reports.

[6]  A. van Oudenaarden,et al.  Snowdrift game dynamics and facultative cheating in yeast , 2009, Nature.

[7]  Long Wang,et al.  Interactive diversity promotes the evolution of cooperation in structured populations , 2016 .

[8]  M. Guyer,et al.  “Public” Choice and Cooperation in n-Person Prisoner's Dilemma , 1978 .

[9]  Martin A Nowak,et al.  Evolutionary dynamics in set structured populations , 2009, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[10]  M. Nowak,et al.  Evolutionary dynamics in structured populations , 2010, Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences.

[11]  Tore Opsahl,et al.  Clustering in weighted networks , 2009, Soc. Networks.

[12]  D. E. Matthews Evolution and the Theory of Games , 1977 .

[13]  D. Fudenberg,et al.  Emergence of cooperation and evolutionary stability in finite populations , 2004, Nature.

[14]  F. C. Santos,et al.  Evolutionary dynamics of collective action in N-person stag hunt dilemmas , 2009, Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences.

[15]  Chaitanya S. Gokhale,et al.  Evolutionary games in the multiverse , 2010, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[16]  H. Ohtsuki,et al.  Breaking the symmetry between interaction and replacement in evolutionary dynamics on graphs. , 2007, Physical review letters.

[17]  Attila Szolnoki,et al.  Topology-independent impact of noise on cooperation in spatial public goods games. , 2009, Physical review. E, Statistical, nonlinear, and soft matter physics.

[18]  Martin A Nowak,et al.  Spatial dilemmas of diffusible public goods , 2013, eLife.

[19]  H. Ohtsuki,et al.  Strategy selection in structured populations. , 2009, Journal of theoretical biology.

[20]  Michael Doebeli,et al.  A simple and general explanation for the evolution of altruism , 2009, Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences.

[21]  Martin A. Nowak,et al.  Games on graphs , 2014 .

[22]  Arne Traulsen,et al.  Coevolution of strategy and structure in complex networks with dynamical linking. , 2006, Physical review letters.

[23]  M. Nowak Five Rules for the Evolution of Cooperation , 2006, Science.

[24]  Y.-Y. Liu,et al.  The fundamental advantages of temporal networks , 2016, Science.

[25]  Matjaz Perc,et al.  Does strong heterogeneity promote cooperation by group interactions? , 2011, ArXiv.

[26]  M. Archetti,et al.  Cooperation as a volunteer’s dilemma and the strategy of conflict in public goods games , 2009, Journal of evolutionary biology.

[27]  Martin A. Nowak,et al.  Spatial structure often inhibits the evolution of cooperation in the snowdrift game , 2022 .

[28]  Martin A. Nowak,et al.  Evolution of cooperation by phenotypic similarity , 2008, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[29]  Peter D. Taylor,et al.  Evolution of cooperation in a finite homogeneous graph , 2007, Nature.

[30]  C. Hauert,et al.  Social evolution in structured populations , 2014, Nature Communications.

[31]  H. Ohtsuki,et al.  A simple rule for the evolution of cooperation on graphs and social networks , 2006, Nature.

[32]  Martin A. Nowak,et al.  Evolutionary dynamics on graphs , 2005, Nature.

[33]  David G. Rand,et al.  Static network structure can stabilize human cooperation , 2014, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[34]  F. C. Santos,et al.  Social diversity promotes the emergence of cooperation in public goods games , 2008, Nature.

[35]  C. Hauert,et al.  Reputation-based partner choice promotes cooperation in social networks. , 2008, Physical review. E, Statistical, nonlinear, and soft matter physics.

[36]  Long Wang,et al.  Evolutionary dynamics under interactive diversity , 2017 .

[37]  H. Ohtsuki,et al.  Evolution of cooperation by phenotypic similarity , 2009, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[38]  A. Vespignani,et al.  The architecture of complex weighted networks. , 2003, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America.

[39]  Josef Hofbauer,et al.  Evolutionary Games and Population Dynamics , 1998 .

[40]  Martin A. Nowak,et al.  Evolutionary dynamics on any population structure , 2016, Nature.

[41]  Arne Traulsen,et al.  Evolutionary Games of Multiplayer Cooperation on Graphs , 2016, bioRxiv.