The exact bias of the Banzhaf measure of power when votes are neither equiprobable nor independent

This paper discusses a numerical scheme for computing the Banzhaf swing probability when votes are neither equiprobable nor independent. Examples indicate a substantial bias in the Banzhaf measure of voting power if neither assumption is met. The analytical part derives the exact magnitude of the bias due to the common probability of an affirmative vote deviating from one half and due to common correlation in unweighted simple-majority games. The former bias is polynomial, the latter is linear. A modified square-root rule for two-tier voting systems that takes into account both the homogeneity and the size of constituencies is also provided.

[1]  Gary Chamberlain,et al.  A note on the probability of casting a decisive vote , 1981 .

[2]  G. Owen Multilinear Extensions of Games , 1972 .

[3]  S. Berg Condorcet's jury theorem revisited , 1993 .

[4]  S. Berg Paradox of voting under an urn model: The effect of homogeneity , 1985 .

[5]  Salvador Barberà,et al.  On the Weights of Nations: Assigning Voting Weights in a Heterogeneous Union , 2004, Journal of Political Economy.

[6]  A. Kirman,et al.  European economic decision-making policy: progress or paralysis? , 1995 .

[7]  Jonathan N. Katz,et al.  The Mathematics and Statistics of Voting Power , 2002 .

[8]  Martin Shubik,et al.  A Method for Evaluating the Distribution of Power in a Committee System , 1954, American Political Science Review.

[9]  Banzhaf,et al.  One Man, 3.312 Votes: A Mathematical Analysis of the Electoral College , 1968 .

[10]  D. Leech,et al.  Voting power and voting blocs , 2004 .

[11]  S. Berg Condorcet's jury theorem, dependency among jurors , 1993 .

[12]  Y. M. Kaniovski,et al.  Risk assessment for credit portfolios: A coupled Markov chain model , 2007 .

[13]  George Tsebelis,et al.  Decision Making in Political Systems: Veto Players in Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, Multicameralism and Multipartyism , 1995, British Journal of Political Science.

[14]  Bernard Grofman,et al.  FAIR APPORTIONMENT AND THE BANZHAF INDEX , 1981 .

[15]  E. S. Pearson,et al.  ON THE USE AND INTERPRETATION OF CERTAIN TEST CRITERIA FOR PURPOSES OF STATISTICAL INFERENCE PART I , 1928 .

[16]  D. Leech An Empirical Comparison of the Performance of Classical Power Indices , 2002 .

[17]  K. Ladha Condorcet's jury theorem in light of de Finetti's theorem , 1993 .

[18]  Dieter Schmidtchenb,et al.  Strategic power in the European Union: Evaluating the distribution of power in policy games , 1998 .

[19]  B. Grofman,et al.  A Unified Theory of Voting: Directional and Proximity Spatial Models , 1999 .

[20]  Alastair R. Hall,et al.  Generalized Method of Moments , 2005 .

[21]  I. J. Good,et al.  Estimating the efficacy of a vote , 1975 .

[22]  Guillermo Owen,et al.  Evaluation of a Presidential Election Game , 1975, American Political Science Review.

[23]  P. Straffin Power and stability in politics , 1994 .

[24]  K. Ladha The Condorcet Jury Theorem, Free Speech and Correlated Votes , 1992 .

[25]  Nicola Maaser,et al.  Equal representation in two-tier voting systems , 2007, Soc. Choice Welf..

[26]  Andrew Gelman,et al.  Standard Voting Power Indexes Do Not Work: An Empirical Analysis , 2002, British Journal of Political Science.

[27]  P. Boland Majority Systems and the Condorcet Jury Theorem , 1989 .

[28]  Dan S. Felsenthal,et al.  Voting power measurement: a story of misreinvention , 2005, Soc. Choice Welf..

[29]  Robert T. Clemen,et al.  Combining Overlapping Information , 1987 .

[30]  M. Holler,et al.  Citations (this article cites 26 articles hosted on the SAGE Journals Online and HighWire Press platforms): , 2005 .

[31]  B. Steunenberg,et al.  Strategic Power in the European Union , 1999 .

[32]  J. Reveley Path Dependence , 2008, Prisoners of the Past.

[33]  Manfred J. Holler,et al.  Power and Preferences Again , 2005 .

[34]  George Tsebelis,et al.  Even More Reasons to Resist the Temptation of Power Indices in the EU , 2001 .

[35]  L. Penrose The Elementary Statistics of Majority Voting , 1946 .

[36]  D. Felsenthal,et al.  The Measurement of Voting Power: Theory and Practice, Problems and Paradoxes , 1998 .

[37]  P. Straffin Homogeneity, independence, and power indices , 1977 .

[38]  Mika Widgrén,et al.  Probabilistic Voting Power in the EU Council: The Cases of Trade Policy and Social Regulation , 1995 .

[39]  James Joseph Biundo,et al.  Analysis of Contingency Tables , 1969 .

[40]  Dennis Leech,et al.  Power indices and probabilistic voting assumptions , 1990 .

[41]  Mika Widgrén,et al.  Power Measurement as Sensitivity Analysis , 2004 .

[42]  D. Leech Power Indices as an Aid to Institutional Design: The Generalised Apportionment Problem , 2002 .

[43]  Edward M. Bolger,et al.  A value for games withn players andr alternatives , 1993 .

[44]  Stefan Napel,et al.  The Possibility of a Preference-Based Power Index , 2005 .