adaPTiVe MechaNis Ms Fo R TReaTiNg Missi Ng iNFoRMaTioN: a s iMula TioN sT udy

People often make inferences with incomplete information. Previous research has led to a mixed picture of how people treat missing information. To explain these results, the authors follow the Brunswikian perspective on human inference and hypothesize that the mechanism’s accuracy for treating missing information depends on how it is distributed in a certain environment. The hypothesis is supported by the results of a simulation study, which also shows that the mechanism for treating missing information has a much stronger impact on overall accuracy than the most accurate inference strategies considered. The conclusion is that how people react to missing information could be an adaptive response to specific environments. When making inferences, people are often confronted with incomplete information. Looking for a healthy meal at a restaurant, for instance, we often do not have much detail about the entrees on the menu (e.g., the amount of cholesterol, fat, or preservatives in the dishes, or the cooking methods used) to help us infer which dish would be the wisest choice. Nevertheless, even with incomplete information, people infer which is the healthier option and make their choices. In the present article, the question addressed is how people should make inferences despite incomplete information.

[1]  Ulrich Hoffrage,et al.  When One Cue is not Enough: Combining Fast and Frugal Heuristics with Compound Cue Processing , 2007, Quarterly journal of experimental psychology.

[2]  Richard D. Johnson,et al.  Making judgments when information is missing: inferences, biases, and framing effects. , 1987, Acta psychologica.

[3]  Ulrich Hoffrage,et al.  Compound cue processing within the fast and frugal heuristics approach in nonlinearly separable environments , 2007 .

[4]  E. Brunswik Perception and the Representative Design of Psychological Experiments , 1957 .

[5]  Arthur B. Markman,et al.  Processing Product Unique Features , 2001 .

[6]  James Jaccard,et al.  The effects of incomplete information on the formation of attitudes toward behavioral alternatives. , 1988 .

[7]  Derek J. Koehler,et al.  Missing information in multiple-cue probability learning , 2004, Memory & cognition.

[8]  D. Goldstein,et al.  Betting on one good reason : The Take the Best heuristic , 1999 .

[9]  Ulrich Hoffrage,et al.  Inferences under time pressure: how opportunity costs affect strategy selection. , 2008, Acta psychologica.

[10]  Ulrich Hoffrage,et al.  How causal knowledge simplifies decision-making , 2006, Minds and Machines.

[11]  Nick Chater,et al.  Fast, frugal, and rational: How rational norms explain behavior , 2003 .

[12]  David H. Krantz,et al.  The psychology of moderate prediction : I. Experience with multiple determination , 1990 .

[13]  J. Rieskamp Positive and negative recency effects in retirement savings decisions. , 2006, Journal of experimental psychology. Applied.

[14]  Eric J. Johnson,et al.  Adaptive Strategy Selection in Decision Making. , 1988 .

[15]  G. Gigerenzer,et al.  Probabilistic mental models: a Brunswikian theory of confidence. , 1991, Psychological review.

[16]  Paul Slovic,et al.  Dimensional Commensurability and Cue Utilization in Comparative Judgment. , 1974 .

[17]  Andrew S. Glassner,et al.  Upon Reflection , 1999, Science.

[18]  Toshio Yamagishi,et al.  Adding versus averaging models revisited: A test of a path-analytic integration model. , 1981 .

[19]  P. Todd,et al.  Simple Heuristics That Make Us Smart , 1999 .

[20]  Arthur B. Markman,et al.  Overcoming the Early Entrant Advantage: The Role of Alignable and Nonalignable Differences , 1998 .

[21]  John G. Lynch,et al.  Inference Effects without Inference Making? Effects of Missing Information on Discounting and Use of Presented Information , 1991 .

[22]  R. Meyer A Model of Multiattribute Judgments under Attribute Uncertainty and Informational Constraint , 1981 .

[23]  Marc Nerlove,et al.  RETURNS TO SCALE IN ELECTRICITY SUPPLY , 1961 .

[24]  Arnold Zellner,et al.  Generalized Production Functions , 1969 .

[25]  Frank R. Kardes,et al.  The role of prior knowledge and missing information in multiattribute evaluation , 1992 .

[26]  Robin M. Hogarth,et al.  Ignoring information in binary choice with continuous variables: When is less “more”? , 2005 .

[27]  Jeen-Su Lim,et al.  Impact of consumers' confidence in judgements about missing information on product evaluations , 1992 .

[28]  J. Rieskamp,et al.  SSL: a theory of how people learn to select strategies. , 2006, Journal of experimental psychology. General.

[29]  I P Levin,et al.  Information integration in price-quality tradeoffs: The effect of missing information , 1984, Memory & cognition.

[30]  W. Greene,et al.  Economies of Scale in U.S. Electric Power Generation , 1976, Journal of Political Economy.

[31]  R. Olshavsky,et al.  The Impact of Inferences on Product Evaluations: Replication and Extension , 1988 .

[32]  Irwin P. Levin,et al.  MEASUREMENT OF PSYCHOLOGICAL FACTORS AND THEIR ROLE IN TRAVEL BEHAVIOR , 1977 .

[33]  J. Simpson,et al.  Rainfall Results, 1970-1975: Florida Area Cumulus Experiment , 1977, Science.

[34]  Ulrich Hoffrage,et al.  When do people use simple heuristics, and how can we tell? , 1999 .

[35]  Richard D. Johnson,et al.  Making Decisions With Incomplete Information: the First Complete Test of the Inference Model , 1989 .

[36]  Jörg Rieskamp,et al.  Perspectives of probabilistic inferences: Reinforcement learning and an adaptive network compared. , 2006, Journal of experimental psychology. Learning, memory, and cognition.

[37]  J. Frank Yates,et al.  Evaluation of Partially Described Multiattribute Options , 1978 .

[38]  U. Czienskowski,et al.  Compound Cue Processing in Linearly and Nonlinearly Separable Environments , 2008 .

[39]  Magnus Persson,et al.  PROBabilities from EXemplars (PROBEX): a "lazy" algorithm for probabilistic inference from generic knowledge , 2002 .

[40]  R. García-Retamero The Influence of Knowledge About Causal Mechanisms on Compound Processing , 2007 .

[41]  T Allison,et al.  Sleep in mammals: ecological and constitutional correlates. , 1976, Science.

[42]  Jerome S. Bruner,et al.  Contemporary approaches to cognition , 1958 .

[43]  Irwin P. Levin,et al.  More than Meets the Eye: The Effect of Missing Information on Purchase Evaluations , 1985 .

[44]  E. Brunswik Organismic achievement and environmental probability. , 1943 .

[45]  Robin M. Hogarth,et al.  "Take-the-best" and other simple strategies: Why and when they work "well" with binary cues , 2006 .

[46]  D. Goldstein,et al.  How good are simple heuristics , 1999 .

[47]  Eric J. Johnson,et al.  The adaptive decision maker , 1993 .

[48]  Joel Huber,et al.  The Impact of Inferential Beliefs on Product Evaluations , 1982 .

[49]  G Gigerenzer,et al.  Reasoning the fast and frugal way: models of bounded rationality. , 1996, Psychological review.

[50]  Kim J. Vicente,et al.  Beyond the Lens Model and Direct Perception: Toward a Broader Ecological Psychology , 2003 .

[51]  R. Hogarth,et al.  Heuristic and linear models of judgment: matching rules and environments. , 2007, Psychological review.

[52]  John R. Anderson Is human cognition adaptive? , 1991, Behavioral and Brain Sciences.

[53]  A. Bröder,et al.  Take the best versus simultaneous feature matching: probabilistic inferences from memory and effects of representation format. , 2003, Journal of experimental psychology. General.

[54]  Jörg Rieskamp,et al.  How do people learn to allocate resources? Comparing two learning theories. , 2003, Journal of experimental psychology. Learning, memory, and cognition.

[55]  P. Raven,et al.  Species Number and Endemism: The Gal�pagos Archipelago Revisited , 1973, Science.

[56]  A. Tversky Intransitivity of preferences. , 1969 .

[57]  Irwin P. Levin,et al.  Framing effects in judgment tasks with varying amounts of information , 1985 .