Smart Matching Platforms and Heterogeneous Beliefs in Centralized School Choice

Many school districts with centralized school choice adopt strategyproof assignment mechanisms to relieve applicants of the need to strategize on the basis of beliefs about their own admissions chances. This paper shows that beliefs about admissions chances shape choice outcomes even when the assignment mechanism is strategyproof by influencing the way applicants search for schools, and that “smart matching platforms” that provide live feedback on admissions chances help applicants search more effectively. Motivated by a model in which applicants engage in costly search for schools and over-optimism can lead to under-search, we use data from a large-scale survey of choice participants in Chile to show that learning about schools is hard, that beliefs about admissions chances guide the decision to stop searching, and that applicants systematically underestimate non-placement risk. We then use RCT and RD research designs to evaluate live feedback policies in the Chilean and New Haven choice systems. 22% of applicants submitting applications where risks of non-placement are high respond to warnings by adding schools to their lists, reducing non-placement risk by 58%. These results replicate across settings and over time. Reducing the strategic burden of school choice requires not just strategyproofness inside the centralized system, but also choice supports for the strategic decisions that inevitably remain outside of it.

[1]  Christopher Neilson,et al.  Targeted Vouchers, Competition Among Schools, and the Academic Achievement of Poor Students , 2013 .

[2]  Ilya Segal,et al.  Clock Auctions and Radio Spectrum Reallocation , 2020, Journal of Political Economy.

[3]  Nicole Immorlica,et al.  Information Acquisition in Matching Markets: The Role of Price Discovery , 2020 .

[4]  Paulo Somaini,et al.  Demand Analysis Using Strategic Reports: An Application to a School Choice Mechanism , 2014 .

[5]  Peter Bergman,et al.  Is Information Enough? The Effect of Information about Education Tax Benefits on Student Outcomes , 2019, Journal of Policy Analysis and Management.

[6]  Philip Oreopoulos,et al.  The Role of Application Assistance and Information in College Decisions: Results from the H&R Block FAFSA Experiment* , 2012 .

[7]  Parag A. Pathak,et al.  The Welfare Effects of Coordinated Assignment: Evidence from the New York City High School Match , 2017 .

[8]  G NetemeyerRichard,et al.  Financial Literacy, Financial Education, and Downstream Financial Behaviors , 2014 .

[9]  Mira Fischer,et al.  Effects of Timing and Reference Frame of Feedback: Evidence from a Field Experiment , 2018, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[10]  B. Handel,et al.  Managing Intelligence: Skilled Experts and AI in Markets for Complex Products , 2020, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[11]  Dorothea Kübler,et al.  Costly information acquisition in centralized matching markets , 2021, Quantitative Economics.

[12]  Atila Abdulkadiroglu,et al.  School Choice: A Mechanism Design Approach , 2003 .

[13]  Flip Klijn,et al.  Constrained school choice , 2009, J. Econ. Theory.

[14]  Ran I. Shorrer,et al.  Correlation Neglect in Student-to-School Matching , 2019, EC.

[15]  Sendhil Mullainathan,et al.  Poverty Impedes Cognitive Function , 2013, Science.

[16]  Michael Hurwitz,et al.  Impacts of College Board’s RYCP Campaign on Postsecondary Enrollment , 2018, AEA Randomized Controlled Trials.

[17]  H. Oosterbeek,et al.  The Performance of School Assignment Mechanisms in Practice , 2015, Journal of Political Economy.

[18]  José R. Correa,et al.  School Choice in Chile , 2019, EC.

[19]  Parag A. Pathak,et al.  What Really Matters in Designing School Choice Mechanisms , 2017 .

[20]  J. McCall Economics of Information and Job Search , 1970 .

[21]  Parag A. Pathak,et al.  Leveling the Playing Field: Sincere and Sophisticated Players in the Boston Mechanism , 2008 .

[22]  Richard W. Patterson,et al.  Timing is Everything: Evidence from College Major Decisions , 2019, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[23]  Yusuke Narita Match or Mismatch: Learning and Inertia in School Choice , 2016 .

[24]  Tong Wang,et al.  High school admission reform in China: a welfare analysis , 2020 .

[25]  Justine S. Hastings,et al.  The Effects of Earnings Disclosure on College Enrollment Decisions , 2015 .

[26]  Parag A. Pathak,et al.  School Admissions Reform in Chicago and England: Comparing Mechanisms by Their Vulnerability to Manipulation , 2011 .

[27]  Chang-Tai Hsieh,et al.  The effects of generalized school choice on achievement and stratification: Evidence from Chile's voucher program , 2006 .

[28]  Justine S. Hastings,et al.  Information, School Choice, and Academic Achievement: Evidence from Two Experiments , 2007 .

[29]  Robert T. Jensen,et al.  The (Perceived) Returns to Education and the Demand for Schooling , 2010 .

[30]  U. Doraszelski,et al.  Ownership Concentration and Strategic Supply Reduction , 2016 .

[31]  Joshua Hyman Can Light‐Touch College‐Going Interventions Make a Difference? Evidence from a Statewide Experiment in Michigan , 2019, Journal of Policy Analysis and Management.

[32]  A. Roth Who Gets What — and Why: The New Economics of Matchmaking and Market Design , 2015 .

[33]  G. Jin,et al.  The Effect of Information on Product Quality: Evidence from Restaurant Hygiene Grade Cards , 2002 .

[34]  Susan Dynarski,et al.  Closing the Gap: The Effect of Reducing Complexity and Uncertainty in College Pricing on the Choices of Low-Income Students , 2021 .

[35]  R. Thaler,et al.  Smarter information, Smarter Consumers , 2013 .

[36]  Adam J. Kapor,et al.  NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES HETEROGENEOUS BELIEFS AND SCHOOL CHOICE MECHANISMS , 2019 .

[37]  Sarah R. Cohodes,et al.  Leveling the Playing Field for High School Choice: Results from a Field Experiment of Informational Interventions , 2018 .