The Nature of the Farm*

Using a model based on a trade‐off between moral hazard incentives and gains from specialization, this paper explains why farming has generally not converted from small, family‐based firms into large, factory‐style corporate firms. Nature is both seasonal and random, and the interplay of these qualities generates moral hazard, limits the gains from specialization, and causes timing problems between stages of production. By identifying conditions in which these forces vary, we derive testable predictions about the choice of organization and the extent of farm integration. To test these predictions we study the historical development of several agricultural industries and analyze data from a sample of over 1,000 farms in British Columbia and Louisiana. In general, seasonality and randomness so limit the benefits of specialization that family farms are optimal, but when farmers are successful in mitigating the effects of seasonality and random shocks to output, farm organizations gravitate toward factory processes and corporate ownership.

[1]  Frederic L. Pryor The plantation economy as an economic system , 1982 .

[2]  William Cronon,et al.  Changes in the Land , 1983 .

[3]  A. Parikh,et al.  The Economic Theory of Agrarian Institutions. , 1990 .

[4]  José A. Aguiñaga Statistical abstract of the United States 1993 , 1994 .

[5]  Thomas D. Isern,et al.  Custom Combining on the Great Plains: A History , 1981 .

[6]  W. B. History of Agriculture in the Northern United States, 1620–1860 , 1926, Nature.

[7]  M. Nerlove Reflections on the Economic Organization of Agriculture: Traditional, Modern, and Transitional , 1994 .

[8]  J. Macleod,et al.  EFFECTS OF SEEDING DATE, SEED TREATMENT AND FOLIAR SPRAYS ON YIELD AND OTHER AGRONOMIC CHARACTERS OF WHEAT, OATS AND BARLEY , 1975 .

[9]  P. Bardhan The economic theory of agrarian institutions , 1991 .

[10]  J. Brewster The Machine Process in Agriculture and Industry , 1950 .

[11]  V. Ruttan,et al.  Why are farms so small , 1994 .

[12]  Paul Milgrom,et al.  The Firm as an Incentive System , 1994 .

[13]  Wayne D. Rasmussen,et al.  Whereby We Thrive: A History of American Farming, 1607-1972 , 1976 .

[14]  C. R. Knoeber,et al.  Explaining State Bans on Corporate Farming , 1997 .

[15]  S. Masten,et al.  The Costs of Organization , 1991 .

[16]  速水 佑次郎,et al.  The economics of contract choice : an agrarian perspective , 1993 .

[17]  Mark R. Rosenzweig,et al.  Behavioural and material determinants of production relations in agriculture , 1986 .

[18]  H. Demsetz,et al.  Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization , 1975, IEEE Engineering Management Review.

[19]  D. Lueck,et al.  Land Tenure and Agricultural Productivity on Indian Reservations , 1992, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[20]  W. J. Spillman,et al.  Farm Management , 2017, Nature.

[21]  P. Raup Corporate Farming in the United States , 1973, The Journal of Economic History.

[22]  Charles R. Knoeber,et al.  A Real Game of Chicken: Contracts, Tournaments, and the Production of Broilers , 1989 .

[23]  P. Baker,et al.  The Division of Labor , 1981 .

[24]  W. McBride Change in U.S. Livestock Production, 1969-92 , 1997 .

[25]  A. Harrison The Economics of Rural Organization: Theory, Practice and Policy . Edited by K. Hoff, A. Braverman and J. E. Stiglitz. Oxford: Oxford University Press (for the World Bank†) (1993), pp. 590, £53.95, US$59.95. ISBN 0-19-520888-9. , 1995, Experimental Agriculture.

[26]  Earl O. Heady,et al.  Economics of Agricultural Production and Resource Use , 1954 .

[27]  Fred W. Kohlmeyer,et al.  Change in Agriculture: The Northern United States, 1820-1870 , 1971 .

[28]  Lawrence J. Buntin Historical Statistics of the United States: Colonial Times to 1970 , 1976 .

[29]  L. C. Gray History of Agriculture in the Southern United States to 1860 , 1933, Nature.