Rational Imprecision : Information-Processing , Neural , and Choice-Rule Perspectives ∗

People make mistakes. A rationally imprecise decision maker optimally balances the cost of reducing mistakes against the value of choosing correctly. We provide three models of rationally imprecise behavior: (1) an information-processing formulation where the costs of reducing mistakes are modeled as the corresponding reduction in Shannon entropy; (2) a neural implementation in terms of a stochastic and contextdependent utility function consistent with how the brain is thought to represent value; and (3) a choice-rule characterization. Our main result proves an equivalence between these three models which shows that they are different perspectives on the same behavior. The three perspectives answer, respectively, the questions of why rationally imprecise behavior should arise, how it can be implemented within the brain, and what such behavior looks like. ∗Financial support from NIH grant R01DA038063, NYU Stern School of Business, NYU Shanghai, and J.P. Valles is gratefully acknowledged. We have greatly benefited from discussions with Andrew Caplin, Faruk Gul, Kenway Louie, Paula Miret, Anthony Marley, Wolfgang Pesendorfer, Doron Ravid, Shellwyn Weston, Jan Zimmerman, members of the Glimcher Lab at NYU, and seminar audiences at Columbia, HKUST, NYU Shanghai, PHBS Shenzhen, Princeton, and Yale. †Institute for the Interdisciplinary Study of Decision Making, New York University, New York, NY 10012, U.S.A., ksteverson@nyu.edu, https://sites.google.com/site/ksteverson/ ‡Stern School of Business, Tandon School of Engineering, Institute for the Interdisciplinary Study of Decision Making, New York University, New York, NY 10012, U.S.A., adam.brandenburger@stern.nyu.edu, http://www.adambrandenburger.com §Center for Neural Science, Institute for the Interdisciplinary Study of Decision Making, New York University, New York, NY 10012, U.S.A., paul.glimcher@nyu.edu, http://www.neuroeconomics.nyu.edu/people/paul-glimcher/

[1]  C. J. Adkins An introduction to thermal physics , 1987 .

[2]  J. Louviere,et al.  Probabilistic models of set-dependent and attribute-level best-worst choice , 2008 .

[3]  Mel W. Khaw,et al.  Normalization is a general neural mechanism for context-dependent decision making , 2013, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[4]  P. Best,et al.  Spatial processing in the brain: the activity of hippocampal place cells. , 2001, Annual review of neuroscience.

[5]  Filip Matejka,et al.  Rational Inattention to Discrete Choices: A New Foundation for the Multinomial Logit Model , 2011 .

[6]  L. Nystrom,et al.  Tracking the hemodynamic responses to reward and punishment in the striatum. , 2000, Journal of neurophysiology.

[7]  Michael L. Platt,et al.  Neural correlates of decision variables in parietal cortex , 1999, Nature.

[8]  L. Thurstone A law of comparative judgment. , 1994 .

[9]  Drew Fudenberg,et al.  Stochastic Choice and Revealed Perturbed Utility , 2015 .

[10]  C. Sims Implications of rational inattention , 2003 .

[11]  Daniel McFadden,et al.  Modelling the Choice of Residential Location , 1977 .

[12]  Adele Diederich,et al.  Survey of decision field theory , 2002, Math. Soc. Sci..

[13]  P. Glimcher,et al.  Activity in Posterior Parietal Cortex Is Correlated with the Relative Subjective Desirability of Action , 2004, Neuron.

[14]  Rolf Landauer,et al.  Irreversibility and heat generation in the computing process , 1961, IBM J. Res. Dev..

[15]  Christopher P. Puto,et al.  Adding Asymmetrically Dominated Alternatives: Violations of Regularity & the Similarity Hypothesis. , 1981 .

[16]  R. Duncan Luce,et al.  Individual Choice Behavior: A Theoretical Analysis , 1979 .

[17]  Andrew Caplin,et al.  Revealed Preference, Rational Inattention, and Costly Information Acquisition , 2014 .

[18]  J. Aczél,et al.  Lectures on Functional Equations and Their Applications , 1968 .

[19]  P. Glimcher,et al.  Rationalizing Context-Dependent Preferences: Divisive Normalization and Neurobiological Constraints on Choice , 2016 .

[20]  J. Rieskamp,et al.  Rigorously testing multialternative decision field theory against random utility models. , 2014, Journal of experimental psychology. General.

[21]  J. Busemeyer,et al.  Extending the Bounds of Rationality: Evidence and Theories of Preferential Choice , 2006 .

[22]  D. Barraclough,et al.  Prefrontal cortex and decision making in a mixed-strategy game , 2004, Nature Neuroscience.

[23]  P. Glimcher,et al.  The neural correlates of subjective value during intertemporal choice , 2007, Nature Neuroscience.

[24]  H. Simon,et al.  A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice , 1955 .

[25]  A. Pouget,et al.  Variance as a Signature of Neural Computations during Decision Making , 2011, Neuron.

[26]  H. D. Block,et al.  Random Orderings and Stochastic Theories of Responses (1960) , 1959 .

[27]  P. Glimcher,et al.  Dynamic Divisive Normalization Predicts Time-Varying Value Coding in Decision-Related Circuits , 2014, The Journal of Neuroscience.

[28]  Brian Knutson,et al.  Anticipation of Increasing Monetary Reward Selectively Recruits Nucleus Accumbens , 2001, The Journal of Neuroscience.

[29]  F. Attneave Some informational aspects of visual perception. , 1954, Psychological review.

[30]  J. Swait,et al.  Probabilistic Choice (Models) as a Result of Balancing Multiple Goals , 2013 .

[31]  Eero P. Simoncelli,et al.  Computational models of cortical visual processing. , 1996, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America.

[32]  Lars-Göran Mattsson,et al.  Probabilistic choice and procedurally bounded rationality , 2002, Games Econ. Behav..

[33]  J. Hey,et al.  INVESTIGATING GENERALIZATIONS OF EXPECTED UTILITY THEORY USING EXPERIMENTAL DATA , 1994, Experiments in Economics.

[34]  Faruk Gul,et al.  Random Choice as Behavioral Optimization , 2014 .

[35]  Michael N. Shadlen,et al.  Noise, neural codes and cortical organization , 1994, Current Opinion in Neurobiology.

[36]  H. B. Barlow,et al.  Possible Principles Underlying the Transformations of Sensory Messages , 2012 .

[37]  Karl J. Friston,et al.  Dissociable Neural Responses in Human Reward Systems , 2000, The Journal of Neuroscience.

[38]  M. Carandini,et al.  Normalization as a canonical neural computation , 2013, Nature Reviews Neuroscience.

[39]  P. Glimcher,et al.  Reward Value-Based Gain Control: Divisive Normalization in Parietal Cortex , 2011, The Journal of Neuroscience.

[40]  Timothy E. J. Behrens,et al.  Hierarchical competitions subserving multi-attribute choice , 2014, Nature Neuroscience.

[41]  Eero P. Simoncelli,et al.  Natural signal statistics and sensory gain control , 2001, Nature Neuroscience.

[42]  I. Simonson,et al.  Choice Based on Reasons: The Case of Attraction and Compromise Effects , 1989 .

[43]  Herbert A. David,et al.  Order Statistics, Third Edition , 2003, Wiley Series in Probability and Statistics.

[44]  Dino J. Levy,et al.  The root of all value: a neural common currency for choice , 2012, Current Opinion in Neurobiology.

[45]  Paul Glimcher,et al.  Understanding the Hows and Whys of Decision-Making: From Expected Utility to Divisive Normalization. , 2014, Cold Spring Harbor symposia on quantitative biology.

[46]  Joel Davis Brain and Visual Perception: The Story of a 25-Year Collaboration , 2004 .

[47]  T. Singer,et al.  The neural basis of empathy. , 2012, Annual review of neuroscience.