How (not) to pay for advice: A framework for consumer financial protection ☆

This paper investigates the determinants of the compensation structure for brokers who advise customers regarding the suitability of financial products. Our model explains why brokers are commonly compensated indirectly through contingent commissions paid by product providers, even though this compensation structure could lead to biased advice. When customers are wary of the adviser's incentives, contingent commissions can be an effective incentive tool to induce the adviser to learn which specialized product is most suitable for the specific needs of customers. If, instead, customers naively believe they receive unbiased advice, high product prices and correspondingly high commissions become a tool of exploitation. Policy intervention that mandates disclosure of commissions can protect naive consumers and increase welfare. However, prohibiting or capping commissions could have the unintended consequence of stifling the adviser's incentive to acquire information. More vigorous competition benefits consumers and reduces exploitation, but firms have limited incentives to educate naive customers.

[1]  Jstor The journal of economic perspectives , 1987 .

[2]  Ulrike Malmendier,et al.  Contract Design and Self-Control: Theory and Evidence , 2004 .

[3]  Peter Tufano,et al.  Consumer Financial Protection. , 2011, The journal of economic perspectives : a journal of the American Economic Association.

[4]  L. Burlingame,et al.  Kickbacks or Compensation: The Case of Yield Spread Premiums , 2009 .

[5]  J. Zechner,et al.  Intermediated Investment Management , 2010 .

[6]  Jeffrey D. Kubik,et al.  Outsourcing Mutual Fund Management: Firm Boundaries, Incentives and Performance , 2012 .

[7]  Don A. Moore,et al.  The Dirt on Coming Clean: Perverse Effects of Disclosing Conflicts of Interest , 2003, The Journal of Legal Studies.

[8]  B. Carlin Strategic Price Complexity in Retail Financial Markets , 2006 .

[9]  Terence Lim,et al.  Rationality and Analysts' Forecast Bias , 2001 .

[10]  X. Freixas,et al.  Conflicts of Interest, Information Provision and Competition in Banking , 2004 .

[11]  Steffen Meyer,et al.  Trading on Advice , 2010 .

[12]  Peter Tufano,et al.  Assessing the Costs and Benefits of Brokers in the Mutual Fund Industry , 2007 .

[13]  Remunerating Information Providers: Commissions versus Fees in Life Insurance , 1994 .

[14]  Roman Inderst,et al.  Misselling through agents , 2009 .

[15]  Patrick Bolton,et al.  Conflicts of interest, information provision, and competition in the financial services industry , 2007 .

[16]  Gregory Kadlec,et al.  What do Soft-dollars Buy? Performance, Expense Shifting, Agency Costs , 2008 .

[17]  Roman Inderst,et al.  Competition through Commissions and Kickbacks , 2012 .

[18]  M. Ottaviani,et al.  Sales Talk, Cancellation Terms and the Role of Consumer Protection , 2013 .

[19]  J. Sobel,et al.  STRATEGIC INFORMATION TRANSMISSION , 1982 .

[20]  J. Cummins,et al.  The Economics of Insurance Intermediaries , 2006 .

[21]  Anat R. Admati,et al.  A monopolistic market for information , 1986 .

[22]  Juan José Ganuza,et al.  Signal Orderings Based on Dispersion and the Supply of Private Information in Auctions , 2010 .

[23]  Devin M. Shanthikumar,et al.  Are Small Investors Naive About Incentives? , 2007 .

[24]  Erik Durbin Corruptible Advice * , 2006 .

[25]  J. Beshears,et al.  Who Selected Adjustable-Rate Mortgages? Evidence from the 1989-2007 Surveys of Consumer Finances , 2009 .

[26]  Uri Gneezy,et al.  Deception: The Role of Consequences , 2005 .

[27]  Don A. Moore,et al.  The Dirt on Coming Clean: Perverse Effects of Disclosing Conflicts of Interest , 2003, The Journal of Legal Studies.

[28]  S. Moyer Financial Regulatory Reform , 2010 .