Rational market making with probabilistic knowledge

A market maker sets prices over time for wagers that pay out contingent on the future state of the world. The market maker has knowledge of the probability of realizing each state of the world, and of how the price of a bet affects the probability that traders will accept it. We compare the optimal policy for risk-neutral (expected utility maximizing) and Kelly criterion (expected log-utility maximizing) market makers. Computing the optimal policy for a risk-neutral market maker is relatively simple, while computing the optimal policy for a Kelly criterion market maker is challenging, requiring advanced techniques adapted from the computational economics literature to run efficiently. We show that while a risk-neutral market maker has an optimal policy that does not depend on the market maker's state, a Kelly criterion market maker's optimal policy has an intricate dependence on both time and state. Counter-intuitively, a Kelly criterion market maker may offer bets that are myopically irrational with respect to the market maker's beliefs for the entire trading period. In contrast, a risk-neutral market maker never offers a myopically irrational bet.

[1]  A. Kyle Continuous Auctions and Insider Trading , 1985 .

[2]  Lance Fortnow,et al.  Bluffing and Strategic Reticence in Prediction Markets , 2007, WINE.

[3]  John L. Kelly,et al.  A new interpretation of information rate , 1956, IRE Trans. Inf. Theory.

[4]  A. Mas-Colell,et al.  Microeconomic Theory , 1995 .

[5]  Nancy L. Stokey,et al.  Recursive methods in economic dynamics , 1989 .

[6]  David M. Pennock,et al.  Designing Markets for Prediction , 2010, AI Mag..

[7]  Geoffrey J. Gordon Stable Function Approximation in Dynamic Programming , 1995, ICML.

[8]  Sanmay Das,et al.  The effects of market-making on price dynamics , 2008, AAMAS.

[9]  Kenneth L. Judd,et al.  Solving a savings allocation problem by numerical dynamic programming with shape-preserving interpolation , 2000, Comput. Oper. Res..

[10]  M. Teboulle,et al.  AN OLD‐NEW CONCEPT OF CONVEX RISK MEASURES: THE OPTIMIZED CERTAINTY EQUIVALENT , 2007 .

[11]  Sanmay Das,et al.  Instructor Rating Markets , 2013, AAAI.

[12]  Sanmay Das,et al.  Adapting to a Market Shock: Optimal Sequential Market-Making , 2008, NIPS.

[13]  Paul R. Milgrom,et al.  Bid, ask and transaction prices in a specialist market with heterogeneously informed traders , 1985 .

[14]  Joan Feigenbaum,et al.  Computation in a distributed information market , 2003, EC '03.

[15]  Carlos Guestrin,et al.  Max-norm Projections for Factored MDPs , 2001, IJCAI.

[16]  Abraham Othman,et al.  Zero-intelligence agents in prediction markets , 2008, AAMAS.

[17]  Dhananjay K. Gode,et al.  Allocative Efficiency of Markets with Zero-Intelligence Traders: Market as a Partial Substitute for Individual Rationality , 1993, Journal of Political Economy.

[18]  Zizhuo Wang,et al.  A unified framework for dynamic pari-mutuel information market design , 2009, EC '09.

[19]  Stanko Dimitrov,et al.  Non-myopic strategies in prediction markets , 2008, EC '08.

[20]  W. Poundstone Fortune's Formula: The Untold Story of the Scientific Betting System That Beat the Casinos and Wall Street , 2005 .

[21]  J. Stachurski Continuous State Dynamic Programming via Nonexpansive Approximation , 2008 .

[22]  Ferruccio Fontanella,et al.  Shape-preserving bivariate interpolation , 1990 .

[23]  Tuomas Sandholm,et al.  When do markets with simple agents fail? , 2010, AAMAS.

[24]  Lance Fortnow,et al.  Gaming Prediction Markets: Equilibrium Strategies with a Market Maker , 2010, Algorithmica.

[25]  Benjamin Van Roy,et al.  The Linear Programming Approach to Approximate Dynamic Programming , 2003, Oper. Res..

[26]  K. Judd Numerical methods in economics , 1998 .

[27]  David M. Pennock,et al.  A Utility Framework for Bounded-Loss Market Makers , 2007, UAI.