Beyond the Median: Voter Preferences, District Heterogeneity, and Political Representation

Despite the centrality of the median voter prediction in political economy models, overwhelming empirical evidence shows that legislators regularly take positions that diverge significantly from the preferences of the median voter in their districts. However, all these empirical studies to date lack the necessary data to directly measure the preferences of the median voter. We utilize a unique data set consisting of individual‐level voting data that allows us to construct direct measures of voter preferences. We find that legislators are most constrained by the preferences of the median voter in homogeneous districts.

[1]  Imre Horváth,et al.  2 – Critical review of the literature , 1984 .

[2]  D. Brady,et al.  Ideology and interests in congressional voting: The politics of abortion in the U.S. Senate , 1995 .

[3]  Jeffrey B. Lewis,et al.  Estimating Voter Preference Distributions from Individual-Level Voting Data , 2001, Political Analysis.

[4]  J. Heckman,et al.  Linear Probability Models of the Demand for Attributes with an Empirical Application to Estimating the Preferences of Legislators , 1996 .

[5]  Mark A. Zupan,et al.  Capture and Ideology in the Economic Theory of Politics , 1984 .

[6]  K. T. Poole,et al.  Congress: A Political-Economic History of Roll Call Voting , 1997 .

[7]  H. Hotelling Stability in Competition , 1929 .

[8]  J. Snyder SAFE SEATS, MARGINAL SEATS, AND PARTY PLATFORMS: THE LOGIC OF PLATFORM DIFFERENTIATION* , 1994 .

[9]  H. Rosenthal,et al.  A Theory of Divided Government , 1996 .

[10]  N. Schofield,et al.  Instability of Simple Dynamic Games , 1978 .

[11]  Michael A. Bailey,et al.  Heterogeneity and Representation: The Senate and Free Trade , 1998 .

[12]  Morris P. Fiorina,et al.  Representatives, roll calls, and constituencies , 1974 .

[13]  Melvin J. Hinich,et al.  Equilibrium in spatial voting: The median voter result is an artifact , 1977 .

[14]  V. Key,et al.  Politics, parties, and pressure groups , 1948 .

[15]  James M. Enelow,et al.  The Spatial Theory of Voting: An Introduction , 1984 .

[16]  S. Peltzman Constituent Interest and Congressional Voting , 1984, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[17]  J. Matsusaka Initiative and Referendum , 2004 .

[18]  J. Kalt,et al.  The Apparent Ideological Behavior of Legislators: Testing for Principal-Agent Slack in Political Institutions , 1990, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[19]  D. Black The theory of committees and elections , 1959 .

[20]  James J. Heckman,et al.  Linear Probability Models of the Demand for Attributes with an Empirical Application to Estimating the Preferences of Legislators , 1996 .

[21]  D. Wittman Candidates with policy preferences: A dynamic model , 1977 .

[22]  Joshua D. Clinton,et al.  The Statistical Analysis of Roll Call Data , 2004, American Political Science Review.

[23]  R. D. Bock,et al.  Marginal maximum likelihood estimation of item parameters , 1982 .

[24]  C. Swain Black Faces, Black Interests: The Representation of African Americans in Congress , 1993 .

[25]  M. Waters Initiative and referendum almanac , 2003 .

[26]  Stephen V. Marks,et al.  CONSTITUENT INTEREST VS. LEGISLATOR IDEOLOGY: THE ROLE OF POLITICAL OPPORTUNITY COST , 1988 .

[27]  Mathew D. McCubbins,et al.  Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House , 1993 .

[28]  A. Downs An Economic Theory of Democracy , 1957 .

[29]  John H. Aldrich A Downsian Spatial Model with Party Activism , 1983, American Political Science Review.

[30]  Thomas Stratmann How Reelection Constituencies Matter: Evidence from Political Action Committees' Contributions and Congressional Voting , 1996, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[31]  Richard F. Fenno Home Style : House Members in Their Districts , 1978 .

[32]  R. McKelvey General Conditions for Global Intransitivities in Formal Voting Models , 1979 .

[33]  David Lublin The Paradox of Representation , 2020 .

[34]  Steven D. Levitt,et al.  How Do Senators Vote? Disentangling the Role of Voter Preferences, Party Affiliation, and Senate Ideology , 1996 .

[35]  John Londregan,et al.  Estimating Legislators' Preferred Points , 1999, Political Analysis.

[36]  Bruce Bender The Influence of Ideology on Congressional Voting , 1991 .

[37]  David L. Epstein,et al.  Measuring the Electoral and Policy Impact of Majority-Minority Voting Districts: Candidates of Choic , 1999 .

[38]  J. Banks,et al.  Elections, Coalitions, and Legislative Outcomes , 1988, American Political Science Review.

[39]  John H. Aldrich Why parties? : the origin and transformation of political parties in America , 1995 .

[40]  David W. Rohde Parties and leaders in the postreform house , 1991 .

[41]  Thomas Stratmann Campaign Contributions and Congressional Voting: Does the Timing of Contributions Matter? , 1995 .

[42]  Bruce Bender,et al.  Legislator voting and shirking: A critical review of the literature , 1996 .

[43]  K. T. Poole,et al.  A Spatial Model for Legislative Roll Call Analysis , 1985 .

[44]  Paul H. Rubin,et al.  Self-Interest, Ideology, and Logrolling in Congressional Voting , 1979, The Journal of Law and Economics.

[45]  L. Kenny,et al.  An explanation for why senators from the same state vote differently so frequently , 1994 .

[46]  Michael C. Munger,et al.  Legislative Voting and the Economic Theory of Politics , 1995 .

[47]  R. D. Bock,et al.  Marginal maximum likelihood estimation of item parameters: Application of an EM algorithm , 1981 .

[48]  Rainald Borck Ideology and interest groups , 1996 .

[49]  Randall L. Calvert,et al.  The Value of Biased Information: A Rational Choice Model of Political Advice , 1985, The Journal of Politics.

[50]  B. Goff,et al.  On the (mis)measurement of legislator ideology and shirking , 1993 .

[51]  S. Peltzman An Economic Interpretation of the History of Congressional Voting in the Twentieth Century , 1983 .