Mommy tracks and public policy: on self-fulfilling prophecies and gender gaps in promotion

Consider a model with two types of jobs. The profitability of promoting a worker to a fast-track job depends not only on his or her observable talent, but also on incontractible effort. We investigate whether self-fulfilling expectations may lead to higher promotion standards for women. If employers expect women to do more household work than men, thereby exerting less effort in their paid job, then women must be more talented to make promotion profitable. Moreover, specialization in the family will then result in women doing most of the household work. Such self-fulfilling prophecies can be defeated: both affirmative action and family policy can make women spend more effort in the market, which can lead the economy to a non-discriminatory equilibrium. However, we find that it is unlikely that temporary policy can move the economy to a symmetric equilibrium: policy must be made permanent. Anti-discrimination policy need not enhance efficiency, and from a distribution viewpoint this is a policy with both winners and losers.

[1]  Affirmative Action and Efficiency in Education , 2002 .

[2]  Kai A. Konrad,et al.  The bargaining family revisited , 2000 .

[3]  A rmative Action in a Competitive Economy , 1999 .

[4]  E. Phelps The Statistical Theory of Racism and Sexism , 1972 .

[5]  Edward P. Lazear,et al.  Male-Female Wage Differentials in Job Ladders , 1990, Journal of Labor Economics.

[6]  V. Fuchs,et al.  Women's Quest for Economic Equality. , 1989 .

[7]  Statistical Discrimination and E ciency , 1999 .

[8]  Geography of the Family , 2000 .

[9]  Steinar Vagstad On private incentives to acquire household production skills , 2001 .

[10]  R. Pollak,et al.  Separate Spheres Bargaining and the Marriage Market , 1993, Journal of Political Economy.

[11]  P. Francois Gender discrimination without gender difference : Theory and policy responses , 1998 .

[12]  Harry J. Paarsch,et al.  Differences in Wage Distributions Between Canada and the United States: An Application of a Flexible Estimator of Distribution Functions in the Presence of Covariates , 2000 .

[13]  Richard Startz,et al.  Private Discrimination and Social Intervention in Competitive Labor Markets , 1983 .

[14]  Stephen Coate,et al.  Will Affirmative-Action Policies Eliminate Negative Stereotypes? , 1993 .

[15]  H. Joshi Changing Roles of Women in the British Labour Market and the Family , 1990 .

[16]  A. Oswald,et al.  Wages, Profits and Rent-Sharing , 1992 .

[17]  P. Norman Statistical Discrimination and Efficiency , 2000 .

[18]  Kai A. Konrad,et al.  Family Policy with Non Cooperative Families , 1995 .

[19]  Paul R. Milgrom,et al.  Job Discrimination, Market Forces, and the Invisibility Hypothesis , 1987 .

[20]  Kevin Lang,et al.  A Language Theory of Discrimination , 1986 .

[21]  Andrea Moro,et al.  Affirmative Action in a Competitive Economy , 2000, SSRN Electronic Journal.

[22]  J. Hersch The Impact of Nonmarket Work on Market Wages , 1991 .

[23]  Kai A. Konrad,et al.  Geography of the family [Die Geographie der Familie] , 2001 .

[24]  Kenneth J. White,et al.  Introduction to the theory and practice of econometrics--a computer handbook using SHAZAM and SAS : for use with Judge-Hill-Griffiths-Lütkepohl-Lee, Introduction to the theory and practice of econometrics, second edition , 1988 .

[25]  D. Aigner,et al.  Statistical Theories of Discrimination in Labor Markets , 1977 .

[26]  Paul Krugman,et al.  The narrow moving band, the Dutch disease, and the competitive consequences of Mrs. Thatcher : Notes on trade in the presence of dynamic scale economies , 1987 .

[27]  Geert Ridder,et al.  Are women overqualified , 1995 .

[28]  Francine D. Blau,et al.  The economics of women, men, and work , 1987 .

[29]  K. Arrow The Theory of Discrimination , 1971 .

[30]  L. Welling Human capital, true love, and gender roles: is sex destiny? , 1999 .

[31]  E. Ziegel Introduction to the Theory and Practice of Econometrics , 1989 .