Quality improvement vs. advertising support: Which strategy works better for a manufacturer?

We consider a marketing channel with a single manufacturer and a single retailer, where both advertising and quality improvement contribute to the build-up of goodwill. In a non-coop scenario, the retailer controls the advertising efforts while the manufacturer controls the quality improvements and wholesale price. Although improving quality positively contributes to goodwill, it also increases the production cost, thereby reducing the manufacturer's profit. In a coop scenario, the manufacturer supports the retailer's advertising while decreasing his investments in quality. We investigate the conditions under which a coop program is beneficial when such a trade-off occurs. Our results demonstrate that only when advertising significantly contributes to goodwill the manufacturer has an incentive to cooperate and a coop program turns out to be Pareto-improving. Conversely, the retailer is always better off with a coop program. Moreover, the channel is operational- and marketing-driven when quality effectiveness is high independent of advertising effectiveness or when both quality and advertising effectiveness are large. In all other cases, the channel is marketing-driven.

[1]  Georges Zaccour,et al.  A di erential game of retailer promotions Ste en J # rgensena , 2003 .

[2]  Xiuli He,et al.  Cooperative Advertising and Pricing in a Dynamic Stochastic Supply Chain: Feedback Stackelberg Strategies , 2009 .

[3]  Georges Zaccour,et al.  Stackelberg Leadership in a Marketing Channel , 2001, IGTR.

[4]  Georges Zaccour,et al.  Feedback Stackelberg equilibrium strategies when the private label competes with the national brand , 2007, Ann. Oper. Res..

[5]  A. Yeung Strategic supply management, quality initiatives, and organizational performance , 2008 .

[6]  Suresh Chand,et al.  Capacity Allocation for Dynamic Process Improvement with Quality and Demand Considerations , 1996, Oper. Res..

[7]  Georges Zaccour,et al.  On the coordination of dynamic marketing channels and two-part tariffs , 2006, Autom..

[8]  G. Zaccour,et al.  DYNAMIC COOPERATIVE ADVERTISING IN A CHANNEL , 2000 .

[9]  Anand Nair,et al.  Dynamics of competing with quality- and advertising-based goodwill , 2006, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[10]  Charles S. Tapiero,et al.  Production Learning and Quality Control , 1987 .

[11]  József Vörös,et al.  Product balancing under conditions of quality inflation, cost pressures and growth strategies , 2002, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[12]  Ngo Van Long,et al.  Differential Games in Economics and Management Science: List of tables , 2000 .

[13]  Fouad El Ouardighi,et al.  A Dynamic Game of Operations and Marketing Management in a Supply Chain , 2008, IGTR.

[14]  Charles H. Fine A Quality Control Model with Learning Effects , 1988, Oper. Res..

[15]  Georges Zaccour,et al.  Optimal control and differential games : essays in honor of Steffen Jørgensen , 2002 .

[16]  S. Sethi,et al.  A survey of Stackelberg differential game models in supply and marketing channels , 2007 .

[17]  Georges Zaccour,et al.  Production, Manufacturing and Logistics Retail promotions with negative brand image effects: Is cooperation possible? , 2003 .

[18]  Peter M. Kort,et al.  Production, inventory, and pricing under cost and demand learning effects , 1999, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[19]  József Vörös,et al.  The dynamics of price, quality and productivity improvement decisions , 2006, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[20]  Pietro De Giovanni,et al.  The state of the art in static and dynamic games , 2009 .

[21]  G. Zaccour,et al.  Could co-op advertising be a manufacturer's counterstrategy to store brands? , 2006 .

[22]  Charles H. Fine Quality Improvement and Learning in Productive Systems , 1986 .

[23]  Georges Zaccour,et al.  Impact of Retailer’s Myopia on Channel’s Strategies , 2002 .

[24]  S. Jørgensen Optimal production, purchasing and pricing: A differential game approach , 1986 .