Risk Aversion as a Perceptual Bias

The theory of expected utility maximization (EUM) proposed by Bernoulli explains risk aversion as a consequence of diminishing marginal utility of wealth. However, observed choices between risky lotteries are difficult to reconcile with EUM: for example, in the laboratory, subjects’ responses on individual trials involve a random element, and cannot be predicted purely from the terms offered; and subjects often appear to be too risk averse with regard to small gambles (while still accepting sufficiently favorable large gambles) to be consistent with any utility-of-wealth function. We propose a unified explanation for both anomalies, similar to the explanation given for related phenomena in the case of perceptual judgments: they result from judgments based on imprecise (and noisy) mental representation of the decision situation. In this model, risk aversion is predicted without any need for a nonlinear utility-of-wealth function, and instead results from a sort of perceptual bias | but one that represents an optimal Bayesian decision, given the limitations of the mental representation of the situation. We propose a specific quantitative model of the mental representation of a simple lottery choice problem, based on other evidence regarding numerical cognition, and test its ability to explain the choice frequencies that we observe in a laboratory experiment.

[1]  Graham Loomes,et al.  Modelling the Stochastic Component of Behaviour in Experiments: Some Issues for the Interpretation of Data , 2005 .

[2]  A. Tversky,et al.  Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk — Source link , 2007 .

[3]  N. Wilcox Stochastic models for binary discrete choice under risk: a critical primer and econometric comparison , 2008 .

[4]  Paul B. Buckley,et al.  Comparisons of digits and dot patterns. , 1974, Journal of experimental psychology.

[5]  Xue-Xin Wei,et al.  A Bayesian observer model constrained by efficient coding can explain 'anti-Bayesian' percepts , 2015, Nature Neuroscience.

[6]  Steven J. Cox,et al.  Mathematics for Neuroscientists , 2010 .

[7]  Judy Czylok A SENSE OF TOUCH , 1979, Nursing standard (Royal College of Nursing (Great Britain) : 1987).

[8]  J. Ross Visual Discrimination of Number without Counting , 2003, Perception.

[9]  Andreas Nieder,et al.  A Labeled-Line Code for Small and Large Numerosities in the Monkey Prefrontal Cortex , 2007, The Journal of Neuroscience.

[10]  Rochel Gelman,et al.  Variability signatures distinguish verbal from nonverbal counting for both large and small numbers , 2001, Psychonomic bulletin & review.

[11]  P. G. Vos,et al.  A probabilistic model for the discrimination of visual number , 1982, Perception & psychophysics.

[12]  E. L. Kaufman,et al.  The discrimination of visual number. , 1949, The American journal of psychology.

[13]  N. Netzer Evolution of Time Preferences and Attitudes Towards Risk , 2009 .

[14]  L E Krueger,et al.  Perceived numerosity: A comparison of magnitude production, magnitude estimation, and discrimination judgments , 1984, Perception & psychophysics.

[15]  M. Rabin,et al.  Reference-Dependent Risk Attitudes , 2007 .

[16]  J. Simmons,et al.  Perceived numerosity as a function of array number, speed of array development, and density of array items , 1991 .

[17]  Philippe Pinel,et al.  Tuning Curves for Approximate Numerosity in the Human Intraparietal Sulcus , 2004, Neuron.

[18]  Ellen Peters,et al.  Development and Testing of an Abbreviated Numeracy Scale: A Rasch Analysis Approach , 2012, Journal of behavioral decision making.

[19]  Jakub Steiner,et al.  Perceiving Prospects Properly , 2016 .

[20]  W. Banks,et al.  Semantic congruity effects in comparative judgments of magnitudes of digits. , 1976 .

[21]  Neil Stewart,et al.  How to Make Loss Aversion Disappear and Reverse: Tests of the Decision by Sampling Origin of Loss Aversion , 2014, Journal of experimental psychology. General.

[22]  S. Frederick Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 19, Number 4—Fall 2005—Pages 25–42 Cognitive Reflection and Decision Making , 2022 .

[23]  T. Indow,et al.  Scaling of dot numerosity , 1977 .

[24]  Frederick Mosteller,et al.  An Experimental Measurement of Utility , 1951, Journal of Political Economy.

[25]  J. Cantlon,et al.  Shared System for Ordering Small and Large Numbers in Monkeys and Humans , 2006, Psychological science.

[26]  Ido Erev,et al.  The rejection of attractive gambles, loss aversion, and the lemon avoidance heuristic , 2008 .

[27]  Eero P. Simoncelli,et al.  Noise characteristics and prior expectations in human visual speed perception , 2006, Nature Neuroscience.

[28]  S. Dehaene,et al.  Representation of number in the brain. , 2009, Annual review of neuroscience.

[29]  Joshua A. Solomon,et al.  Orientation uncertainty reduces perceived obliquity , 2010, Vision Research.

[30]  D. Hubel,et al.  Receptive fields of single neurones in the cat's striate cortex , 1959, The Journal of physiology.

[31]  Charles A. Holt,et al.  Risk Aversion and Incentive Effects , 2002 .

[32]  Stanislas Dehaene,et al.  Two mental calculation systems: A case study of severe acalculia with preserved approximation , 1991, Neuropsychologia.

[33]  N. Wilcox,et al.  Decisions, Error and Heterogeneity , 1997 .

[34]  S. Appelle Perception and discrimination as a function of stimulus orientation: the "oblique effect" in man and animals. , 1972, Psychological bulletin.

[35]  J. Jastrow Studies from the University of Wisconsin: On the Judgment of Angles and Positions of Lines , 1892 .

[36]  S. Dehaene,et al.  Exact and Approximate Arithmetic in an Amazonian Indigene Group , 2004, Science.

[37]  Arthur J. Robson,et al.  The Biological Basis of Economic Behavior , 2001 .

[38]  P. Glimcher Foundations of Neuroeconomic Analysis , 2010 .

[39]  David C. Burr,et al.  Linear mapping of numbers onto space requires attention , 2012, Cognition.

[40]  M. Rabin Risk Aversion and Expected Utility Theory: A Calibration Theorem , 2000 .

[41]  Andreas Nieder,et al.  Coding of abstract quantity by ‘number neurons’ of the primate brain , 2012, Journal of Comparative Physiology A.

[42]  Stanislas Dehaene,et al.  Cognitive euroscience: Scalar variability in price estimation and the cognitive consequences of switching to the euro , 2002, The Quarterly journal of experimental psychology. A, Human experimental psychology.

[43]  Richard F. Thompson,et al.  Number Coding in Association Cortex of the Cat , 1970, Science.

[44]  Matthew Rabin,et al.  Revealed Mistakes and Revealed Preferences , 2008 .

[45]  Jesse M. Shapiro,et al.  WHO IS 'BEHAVIORAL'? COGNITIVE ABILITY AND ANOMALOUS PREFERENCES. , 2013, Journal of the European Economic Association.

[46]  David I. Laibson,et al.  Myopia and Discounting , 2017 .

[47]  C. Gallistel,et al.  Nonverbal Counting in Humans: The Psychophysics of Number Representation , 1999 .

[48]  Michael Woodford,et al.  Prospect Theory as Efficient Perceptual Distortion , 2012 .

[49]  Lester E. Krueger,et al.  Perceived numerosity , 1972 .

[50]  J. B. S. HALDANE,et al.  Number: the Language of Science , 1941, Nature.

[51]  A Kacelnik,et al.  Risky choice and Weber's Law. , 1998, Journal of theoretical biology.

[52]  Stanislas Dehaene,et al.  Calibrating the mental number line , 2008, Cognition.

[53]  Marco Zorzi,et al.  Numerosity Estimation in Visual Stimuli in the Absence of Luminance-Based Cues , 2011, PloS one.

[54]  The S-Shaped Value Function as a Constrained Optimum , 1989 .

[55]  ROBERT S. MOYER,et al.  Time required for Judgements of Numerical Inequality , 1967, Nature.

[56]  Gustav Theodor Fechner,et al.  Elements of psychophysics , 1966 .

[57]  Eero P. Simoncelli,et al.  Cardinal rules: Visual orientation perception reflects knowledge of environmental statistics , 2011, Nature Neuroscience.

[58]  James C. Cox,et al.  Is there a plausible theory for decision under risk? A dual calibration critique , 2010 .

[59]  M. Rabin,et al.  A Model of Reference-Dependent Preferences , 2006 .

[60]  J. Hey Experimental investigations of errors in decision making under risk , 2018, Experiments in Economics.

[61]  Sid Kouider,et al.  An oblique illusion modulated by visibility: non-monotonic sensory integration in orientation processing. , 2010, Journal of vision.

[62]  S. Dehaene Symbols and quantities in parietal cortex: elements of a mathematical theory of number representation and manipulation , 2007 .

[63]  Robert Sugden,et al.  Incorporating a stochastic element into decision theories , 1995 .

[64]  D. Bernoulli Exposition of a New Theory on the Measurement of Risk , 1954 .

[65]  G. Becker,et al.  Evolutionary Efficiency and Happiness , 2007, Journal of Political Economy.

[66]  John D. Hey Does Repetition Improve Consistency? , 2001 .

[67]  B. O'Shaughnessy The sense of touch , 1989 .