Global identification of risk preferences with revealed preference data

The concept of parameter identification (for a given specification) is differentiated from global identification (which specification is right). First-order conditions for production under risk are shown to admit many alternative specification pairs representing risk preferences and either perceived price risk, production risk, or the deterministic production structure. Imposing an arbitrary specification on any of the latter three determines which risk preference specification fits a given dataset, undermining global identification even when parameter identification is suggested by typical statistics. This lack of identification is not relaxed by increasing the number of observations. Critical implications for estimation of mean-variance specifications are derived.

[1]  W. Griffiths,et al.  Estimating State‐Contingent Production Frontiers , 2006 .

[2]  M. Machina Choice under Uncertainty: Problems Solved and Unsolved , 1987 .

[3]  Jack Meyer,et al.  Two Moment Decision Models And Expected Utility Maximization: Some Implications For Applied Research , 1988 .

[4]  B. Coyle,et al.  Risk Aversion and Yield Uncertainty in Duality Models of Production: A Mean‐Variance Approach , 1999 .

[5]  R. Just,et al.  Stochastic specification of production functions and economic implications , 1978 .

[6]  R. Just Risk Aversion under Profit Maximization , 1975 .

[7]  A. Tversky,et al.  Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk — Source link , 2007 .

[8]  A. Sandmo On the theory of the competitive firm under price uncertainty , 1971 .

[9]  F. Diebold,et al.  The distribution of realized stock return volatility , 2001 .

[10]  J. Antle,et al.  Dynamic Input Decisions in Econometric Production Models , 1986 .

[11]  R. Just,et al.  Adverse Selection in Crop Insurance: Actuarial and Asymmetric Information Incentives , 1999 .

[12]  R. Chou,et al.  ARCH modeling in finance: A review of the theory and empirical evidence , 1992 .

[13]  Jay Shanken,et al.  Intertemporal asset pricing: An Empirical Investigation , 1990 .

[14]  Quinn Weninger,et al.  Are Crop Yields Normally Distributed? , 1999 .

[15]  Production Function Estimation: Reviving the Primal , 1996 .

[16]  C. Shumway,et al.  Joint Estimation of Risk Preference Structure and Technology Using Expo-Power Utility , 1994 .

[17]  D. L. Hanson,et al.  ON THE THEORY OF RISK AVERSION , 1970 .

[18]  D. McFadden,et al.  Production Economics: A Dual Approach to Theory and Applications (I): The Theory of Production , 1978 .

[19]  D Kaplan,et al.  The Impact of Specification Error on the Estimation, Testing, and Improvement of Structural Equation Models. , 1988, Multivariate behavioral research.

[20]  J. Pratt RISK AVERSION IN THE SMALL AND IN THE LARGE11This research was supported by the National Science Foundation (grant NSF-G24035). Reproduction in whole or in part is permitted for any purpose of the United States Government. , 1964 .

[21]  R. Pope A new parametric test for the structure of risk preferences , 1988 .

[22]  John Quiggin,et al.  Uncertainty, production, choice, and agency , 2000 .

[23]  J. Behrman Supply response in underdeveloped agriculture; a case study of four major annual crops in Thailand, 1937-1963. , 1969 .

[24]  A. Tversky,et al.  Prospect Theory : An Analysis of Decision under Risk Author ( s ) : , 2007 .

[25]  J. Hey,et al.  INVESTIGATING GENERALIZATIONS OF EXPECTED UTILITY THEORY USING EXPERIMENTAL DATA , 1994, Experiments in Economics.

[26]  J. Drèze,et al.  Specification and estimation of Cobb-Douglas production function models , 1966 .

[27]  F. Diebold,et al.  The dynamics of exchange rate volatility: a multivariate latent factor ARCH model , 1986 .

[28]  R. Pope The Generalized Envelope Theorem and Price Uncertainty , 1980 .

[29]  V. Smith Microeconomic Systems as an Experimental Science , 1982 .

[30]  G. Judge,et al.  The Theory and Practice of Econometrics , 1981 .

[31]  Steven T. Buccola,et al.  Joint Risk Preference-Technology Estimation with a Primal System , 1991 .

[32]  R. Pope,et al.  Price uncertainty and competitive firm behavior: Testable hypotheses from expected utility maximization , 1985 .

[33]  R. Just,et al.  Empirical implementation of ex ante cost functions , 1996 .

[34]  H. P. Binswanger Attitudes toward Risk: Theoretical Implications of an Experiment in Rural India , 1981 .

[35]  A. Stuart,et al.  Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments , 1959 .

[36]  Yasuo Amemiya,et al.  Instrumental variable estimator for the nonlinear errors-in-variables model , 1985 .

[37]  Yair Mundlak,et al.  CONSEQUENCES OF ALTERNATIVE SPECIFICATIONS IN ESTIMA- TION OF COBB-DOUGLAS PRODUCTION FUNCTIONS , 1965 .

[38]  J. Quiggin A theory of anticipated utility , 1982 .

[39]  M. Holt,et al.  Economic Behavior under Uncertainty: A Joint Analysis of Risk Preferences and Technology , 1996 .

[40]  G. Frankfurter,et al.  Portfolio Selection: The Effects of Uncertain Means, Variances, and Covariances , 1971, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis.

[41]  K. Arrow,et al.  Aspects of the theory of risk-bearing , 1966 .

[42]  U. Kohli,et al.  Import Price Uncertainty and the Distribution of Income , 1997, Review of Economics and Statistics.

[43]  W. H. Andrews Random Simultaneous Equations and the Theory of Production , 1944 .

[44]  J. Chavas A Cost Approach to Economic Analysis Under State‐Contingent Production Uncertainty , 2008 .

[45]  R. Just Existence of Stable Distributed Lags , 1977 .

[46]  J. Neumann,et al.  Theory of games and economic behavior , 1945, 100 Years of Math Milestones.

[47]  Lawrence J. Lau,et al.  Profit, Supply, and Factor Demand Functions , 1972 .

[48]  J. Antle Econometric Estimation of Producers' Risk Attitudes , 1987 .

[49]  Random Profits and Duality , 2002 .