Intrafirm Trade, Bargaining Power, and Specific Investments

This paper compares the performance of standard-cost with negotiated transfer pricing under asymmetric information. Negotiated transfer pricing generally achieves higher expected contribution margins, as this method tends to be more efficient in aggregating private information into a single transfer price. Standard-cost transfer pricing confers more bargaining power to the supplier and therefore generates better incentives for this division to undertake specific investments. The opposite holds for buyer investments. If a corporate controller has disaggregated information about divisional costs and revenues, then the firm can improve upon the performance of standard-cost transfer pricing by setting a centralized transfer price equal to expected cost plus a suitably chosen mark-up.

[1]  S. Reichelstein,et al.  Specific investment under negotiated transfer pricing: An efficiency result , 1995 .

[2]  Kalyan Chatterjee,et al.  Bargaining under Incomplete Information , 1983, Oper. Res..

[3]  Igor Vaysman,et al.  A model of cost-based transfer pricing , 1996 .

[4]  Roy Radner,et al.  Equilibria of the Sealed- Bid Mechanism for Bargaining with Incomplete Information*, ' , 1987 .

[5]  Alfred Wagenhofer Transfer pricing under asymmetric information: An evaluation of alternative methods , 1994 .

[6]  Raffi J. Indjejikian,et al.  Aggregate performance measures in business unit manager compensation: The role of intrafirm interdependencies , 1995 .

[7]  S. Dutta,et al.  Negotiated Transfer Pricing and Divisional vs. Firm‐Wide Performance Evaluation , 1999 .

[8]  Robert S. Kaplan,et al.  Advanced Management Accounting , 1989 .

[9]  W. Dugger The Economic Institutions of Capitalism , 1987 .

[10]  Igor Vaysman,et al.  A model of negotiated transfer pricing , 1998 .

[11]  Charles H. Kriebel,et al.  Asymmetric Information, Incentives and Intrafirm Resource Allocation , 1982 .

[12]  Kenneth A. Merchant,et al.  Rewarding results : motivating profit center managers , 1989 .

[13]  R. Eccles The Transfer Pricing Problem: A Theory for Practice , 1985 .

[14]  Sanford J. Grossman,et al.  The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration , 1986 .

[15]  Joel S. Demski,et al.  Profit allocation under ancillary trade , 1998 .

[16]  D. Larcker,et al.  Are nonfinancial measures leading indicators of financial performance? An analysis of customer satisfaction , 1998 .

[17]  D. Larcker,et al.  Competition, efficiency, and cost allocation in government agencies: Evidence on the Federal Reserve System , 1998 .

[18]  Jean Tirole,et al.  Transfer Pricing and Organizational Form , 1991 .

[19]  V. Narayanan,et al.  Impact of Competition and Taxes on Responsibility Center Organization and Transfer Prices , 2000 .

[20]  Stefan Reichelstein,et al.  Negotiated versus Cost-Based Transfer Pricing , 1999 .

[21]  M. Satterthwaite,et al.  Efficient Mechanisms for Bilateral Trading , 1983 .

[22]  Amin H. Amershi,et al.  Intrafirm resource allocation: The economics of transfer pricing and cost allocations in accounting* , 1990 .

[23]  A. Edlin,et al.  Strict Monotonicity in Comparative Statics , 1998 .

[24]  Tai-Yeong Chung,et al.  Incomplete Contracts, Specific Investments, and Risk Sharing , 1991 .

[25]  Roger Y. W. Tang Transfer pricing in the 1990s : tax and management perspectives , 1993 .

[26]  Robert G. Eccles,et al.  Price and Authority in Inter-Profit Center Transactions , 1988, American Journal of Sociology.