Collective Risk Control and Group Security: The Unexpected Consequences of Differential Risk Aversion

We provide an analysis of odds-improving self-protection for when it yields collective benefits to groups, such as alliances of nations, for whom risks of loss are public bads and prevention of loss is a public good. Our analysis of common risk reduction shows how diminishing returns in risk improvement can be folded into income effects. These income effects then imply that whether protection is inferior or normal depends on the risk aversion characteristics of underlying utility functions, and on the interaction between these, the level of risk, and marginal effectiveness of risk abatement. We demonstrate how public good inferiority is highly likely when the good is "group risk reduction." In fact, we discover a natural or endogenous limit on the size of a group and of the amount of risk controlling outlay it will provide under Nash behavior. We call this limit an "Inferior Goods Barrier" to voluntary risk reduction. For the paradigm case of declining risk aversion, increases in group size(wealth) will cause provision of more safety to change from a normal to an inferior good thereby creating such a barrier. Copyright 2007 Blackwell Publishing, Inc..

[1]  H. Varian,et al.  On the private provision of public goods , 1986 .

[2]  J. Andreoni Privately provided public goods in a large economy: The limits of altruism , 1988 .

[3]  T. Sandler,et al.  Weakest-link public goods: Giving in-kind or transferring money , 2002 .

[4]  I. Ehrlich,et al.  Market Insurance, Self-Insurance, and Self-Protection , 1972, Journal of Political Economy.

[5]  G. Becker,et al.  A Theory of Social Interactions , 1974, Journal of Political Economy.

[6]  Debraj Ray,et al.  Group Formation in Risk-Sharing Arrangements , 2003 .

[7]  Todd Sandler,et al.  Global Challenges: An Approach to Environmental, Political, and Economic Problems , 1997 .

[8]  R. Cornes,et al.  Aggregative Public Good Games , 2006 .

[9]  D. Mueller Public Choice III: What have we learned? , 1979 .

[10]  T. Sandler Collective versus unilateral responses to terrorism , 2005, Transnational Terrorism.

[11]  J. Andreoni Giving with Impure Altruism: Applications to Charity and Ricardian Equivalence , 1989, Journal of Political Economy.

[12]  J. Hirshleifer From weakest-link to best-shot: The voluntary provision of public goods , 1983 .

[13]  T. L. Schwartz The Logic of Collective Action , 1986 .

[14]  Peter Warr,et al.  The private provision of a public good is independent of the distribution of income , 1983 .

[15]  M. McGuire,et al.  A New Approach to Group Structure, Burden Sharing, and the Equilibrium Provision of Public Goods , 2003 .

[16]  Todd Sandler,et al.  Counterterrorism , 2005 .

[17]  Todd Sandler,et al.  The calculus of dissent: An analysis of terrorists' choice of targets , 1988, Synthese.

[18]  Todd Sandler,et al.  EASY RIDERS, JOINT PRODUCTION, AND PUBLIC GOODS* , 1984 .

[19]  Simon Vicary,et al.  Transfers and the weakest-link: An extension of Hirshleifer's analysis , 1990 .

[20]  M. Olson,et al.  The Logic of Collective Action , 1965 .

[21]  J. Andreoni,et al.  Identifying the free riders: A simple algorithm for determining who will contribute to a public good , 1993 .

[22]  R. Zeckhauser,et al.  An economic theory of alliances , 1966 .

[23]  Toshihiro Ihori International public goods and contribution productivity differentials , 1996 .

[24]  R. Cornes Dyke Maintenance and Other Stories: Some Neglected Types of Public Goods , 1993 .

[25]  R. Hartley,et al.  Joint Production Games And Share Functions , 2000 .

[26]  Todd Sandler,et al.  Collective Action: Theory and Applications , 1992 .

[27]  Martin C. McGuire,et al.  Paying to improve your chances: Gambling or insurance? , 1991 .

[28]  Anthony B. Atkinson,et al.  Lectures on public economics , 1988 .

[29]  Jack Hirshleifer,et al.  From weakest-link to best-shot: Correction , 1985 .

[30]  Todd Sandler,et al.  The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods, and Club Goods , 1986 .