A Bayesian model of quasi-magical thinking can explain observed cooperation in the public good game

Abstract Models of learning, reciprocity and altruism cannot explain all aspects of observed contributions in the public good game. Here a new model is described in which players recognize a correlation between their own contribution and the likely contributions of other players. The correlation is calculated by treating a player's own conjectured contribution just like any other data point within a learning model. Although players recognize that this correlation is not causal, they nevertheless choose to maximize expected utility conditional on their own action rather than standard expected utility. Results from the model explain previously puzzling quantitative trends in the data.

[1]  U. Fischbacher,et al.  Are People Conditionally Cooperative? Evidence from a Public Goods Experiment , 2001 .

[2]  A. Tversky,et al.  Thinking through uncertainty: Nonconsequential reasoning and choice , 1992, Cognitive Psychology.

[3]  James Andreoni,et al.  Why free ride?: Strategies and learning in public goods experiments , 1988 .

[4]  Rachel Croson,et al.  Thinking like a game theorist: factors affecting the frequency of equilibrium play , 2000 .

[5]  Robyn M. Dawes,et al.  The potential nonfalsity of the false consensus effect. , 1990 .

[6]  V. Girotto,et al.  Distinguishing Sources of Cooperation in the One-Round Prisoner's Dilemma: Evidence for Cooperative Decisions Based on the Illusion of Control , 1998 .

[7]  Jacob K. Goeree,et al.  A theoretical analysis of altruism and decision error in public goods games , 1998 .

[8]  Robin M. Hogarth,et al.  Insights in decision making : a tribute to Hillel J. Einhorn , 1990 .

[9]  David M. Kreps,et al.  Rational cooperation in the finitely repeated prisoners' dilemma , 1982 .

[10]  Robert Nozick,et al.  Newcomb’s Problem and Two Principles of Choice , 1969 .

[11]  C. Keser,et al.  Conditional cooperation and voluntary contributions to public goods , 2000 .

[12]  J. Andreoni Giving with Impure Altruism: Applications to Charity and Ricardian Equivalence , 1989, Journal of Political Economy.

[13]  T. Palfrey,et al.  Anomalous Behavior in Public Goods Experiments: How Much and Why? , 1997 .

[14]  Joachim Weimann,et al.  Individual behaviour in a free riding experiment , 1994 .

[15]  G. Becker A Theory of Social Interactions , 1974 .

[16]  Robyn M. Dawes,et al.  The False Consensus Effect and Overconfidence: Flaws in Judgment or Flaws in How We Study Judgment? , 1996 .

[17]  J. Kagel,et al.  Handbook of Experimental Economics , 1997 .

[18]  L. Ross,et al.  The “false consensus effect”: An egocentric bias in social perception and attribution processes , 1977 .

[19]  R. Cornes,et al.  The theory of public goods: non-nash behaviour , 1984 .

[20]  John D. Hey,et al.  Do Anglo-Saxons free-ride more? , 1997 .

[21]  Colin Camerer,et al.  Experience‐weighted Attraction Learning in Normal Form Games , 1999 .

[22]  Jacob M. Rabbie,et al.  Social identity theory: A conceptual and empirical critique from the perspective of a behavioural interaction model , 1989 .

[23]  R. Jeffrey The Logic of Decision , 1984 .

[24]  Robyn M. Dawes,et al.  Behavior, communication, and assumptions about other people's behavior in a commons dilemma situation. , 1977 .

[25]  Rachel T. A. Croson Partners and strangers revisited , 1996 .

[26]  Mark A Walker,et al.  The free rider problem: Experimental evidence , 1984 .

[27]  R. Mark Isaac,et al.  Communication and Free-Riding Behavior: The Voluntary Contribution Mechanism , 1988 .

[28]  David R. Karp,et al.  Raising the minimum in the minimal group paradigm. , 1993 .

[29]  James M. Walker,et al.  Group size and the voluntary provision of public goods : Experimental evidence utilizing large groups , 1994 .

[30]  A I Houston,et al.  Memory and the efficient use of information. , 1987, Journal of theoretical biology.

[31]  Thomas R. Palfrey,et al.  Altruism, Reputation, and Noise in Linear Public Goods Experiments , 1996 .

[32]  Ethan D. Bolker,et al.  A Simultaneous Axiomatization of Utility and Subjective Probability , 1967, Philosophy of Science.

[33]  R. Mark Isaac,et al.  Divergent evidence on free riding: An experimental examination of possible explanations , 1984 .

[34]  J. Andreoni Cooperation in Public-Goods Experiments: Kindness or Confusion? , 1995 .

[35]  Jordi Brandts,et al.  Cooperation and Noise in Public Goods Experiments: Applying the Contribution Function Approach , 1999 .

[36]  Amos Tversky,et al.  Causal versus diagnostic contingencies: On self-deception and on the voter's illusion. , 1984 .

[37]  N. Rescher,et al.  Essays in Honor of Carl G. Hempel , 1969 .

[38]  Charles R. Plott,et al.  Public goods provision in an experimental environment , 1985 .

[39]  James Andreoni,et al.  Can evolutionary dynamics explain free riding in experiments , 1991 .

[40]  J. Ledyard Public Goods: A Survey of Experimental Research , 1994 .

[41]  John Orbell,et al.  A “Cognitive Miser” Theory of Cooperators Advantage , 1991, American Political Science Review.

[42]  R. Dawes Statistical criteria for establishing a truly false consensus effect , 1989 .

[43]  H. Rosenthal,et al.  Private incentives in social dilemmas: The effects of incomplete information and altruism , 1988 .