Time Horizon, Costs of Equity Capital, and Generic Investment Strategies of Firms

Recent literature (McNulty, Yeh, Schulze, & Lubatkin, 2002) states that the assumptions behind the capital asset pricing model, in particular the irrelevance of time horizon, do not correspond to the characteristics of firms that prefer long-term investment horizons. I show that family firms display a longer time horizon than most of their nonfamily counterparts, since (1) family firms display a longer CEO tenure, (2) this type of firm strives for long-term independence and succession within the family, and (3) due to the fact that family firms are overrepresented on western European stock markets in cyclical industries in which business cycles inhibit short-term success. As the annual default risk of an investment diminishes with increasing holding period (Hull, 2003), the risk-equivalent cost of equity capital of firms with longer planning horizons (e.g., family firms) can be lower as well. Based on the assumption that economic value to shareholders is created when firms invest in projects with returns above the associated cost of capital (Copeland, Koller, & Murrin, 2000), I argue that long-term-oriented firms can tackle unique investment projects represented by two generic investment strategies—the perseverance and the outpacing strategy. The first one, the perseverance strategy, represents investment strategies in which long-term-oriented firms invest in lower return but equal risk projects than their more short-term-oriented counterparts. The second one, the outpacing strategy, comprises investment projects with higher risk and equal return than the short-term competitors.

[1]  Paul A. Samuelson,et al.  The judgment of economic science on rational portfolio management , 1989 .

[2]  M. Carney Corporate Governance and Competitive Advantage in Family–Controlled Firms , 2005 .

[3]  J. March,et al.  Managerial perspectives on risk and risk taking , 1987 .

[4]  J. Woolridge COMPETITIVE DECLINE AND CORPORATE RESTRUCTURING: IS A MYOPIC STOCK MARKET To BLAME? , 1988 .

[5]  H. Levy,et al.  Portfolio Composition and the Investment Horizon , 1994 .

[6]  M. C. Jensen,et al.  Eclipse of the Public Corporation , 1999 .

[7]  J. Astrachan,et al.  The Importance of Integrated Goal Setting: The Application of Cost-of-Capital Concepts to Private Firms , 2004 .

[8]  R. C. Merton,et al.  Labor Supply Flexibility and Portfolio Choice in a Life-Cycle Model , 1992 .

[9]  David G. Sirmon,et al.  Managing Resources: Linking Unique Resources, Management, and Wealth Creation in Family Firms , 2003 .

[10]  Zellweger , 1974 .

[11]  James J. Chrisman,et al.  Trends and Directions in the Development of a Strategic Management Theory of the Family Firm , 2005 .

[12]  M. Lubatkin,et al.  Toward a Strategic Theory of Risk Premium: Moving Beyond Capm , 1999 .

[13]  John L. Ward,et al.  Growing the Family Business: Special Challenges and Best Practices , 1997 .

[14]  But Will it Raise My Share Price? New Thoughts About an Old Question , 2003 .

[15]  J. Hull Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives , 1989 .

[16]  Sherwin Rosen,et al.  Contracts and the Market for Executives , 1990 .

[17]  Thomas M. Zellweger,et al.  Risk, Return and Value in the Family Firm , 2006 .

[18]  Rudolf Wimmer,et al.  Familienunternehmen - Auslaufmodell oder Erfolgstyp? , 1996 .

[19]  Larry H. P. Lang,et al.  The Ultimate Ownership of Western European Corporations , 2002 .

[20]  M. Lubatkin,et al.  What's your real cost of capital? , 2002, IEEE Engineering Management Review.

[21]  S. M. Keane THE COST OF CAPITAL AS A FINANCIAL DECISION TOOL , 1978 .

[22]  W. Tsai,et al.  CEO Tenure in Taiwanese Family and Nonfamily Firms: An Agency Theory Perspective , 2006 .

[23]  David F. Larcker,et al.  AN ANALYSIS OF THE USE OF ACCOUNTING AND MARKET MEASURES OF PERFORMANCE IN EXECUTIVE-COMPENSATION CONTRACTS , 1987 .

[24]  David J. Teece,et al.  Foreign Investment and Technological Development in Silicon Valley , 1992 .

[25]  D. Miles,et al.  Testing for short-termism in the UK stock market , 1993 .

[26]  M. Lettau,et al.  Time-Varying Risk Premia and the Cost of Capital: An Alternative Implication of the Q Theory of Investment , 2001 .

[27]  W. Lazonick,et al.  Creating and extracting value: Corporate investment behavior and American economic performance , 1994 .

[28]  P. Samuelson LIFETIME PORTFOLIO SELECTION BY DYNAMIC STOCHASTIC PROGRAMMING , 1969 .

[29]  Daniel L. McConaughy,et al.  Is the Cost of Capital Different for Family Firms? , 1999 .

[30]  Paul A. Samuelson,et al.  The Long-Term Case for Equities , 1994 .

[31]  G. Duffee Estimating the Price of Default Risk , 1996 .

[32]  Michael Lubatkin,et al.  The strategy-shareholder value relationship: Testing temporal stability across market cycles , 1991 .

[33]  M. C. Jensen,et al.  The Takeover Controversy: Analysis and Evidence , 2003 .

[34]  W. Sharpe CAPITAL ASSET PRICES: A THEORY OF MARKET EQUILIBRIUM UNDER CONDITIONS OF RISK* , 1964 .

[35]  William P. Rogerson,et al.  Intertemporal Cost Allocation and Managerial Investment Incentives: A Theory Explaining the Use of Economic Value Added as a Performance Measure , 1997, Journal of Political Economy.

[36]  C. Salvato,et al.  A conceptual model of transgenerational entrepreneurship in family-influenced firms , 2006 .

[37]  M. Porter,et al.  Capital disadvantage: America's failing capital investment system. , 1992, Harvard business review.

[38]  J. Lintner THE VALUATION OF RISK ASSETS AND THE SELECTION OF RISKY INVESTMENTS IN STOCK PORTFOLIOS AND CAPITAL BUDGETS , 1965 .

[39]  Charles M. C. Lee,et al.  Toward an Implied Cost of Capital , 2000 .

[40]  William S. Schulze,et al.  Exploring the Agency Consequences of Ownership Dispersion Among The Directors of Private Family Firms , 2003 .

[41]  J. Mossin EQUILIBRIUM IN A CAPITAL ASSET MARKET , 1966 .

[42]  Stephen A. Ross,et al.  The determination of financial structure: the incentive-signalling approach , 1977 .

[43]  Abbie J. Smith,et al.  An Empirical-Investigation Of The Relative Performance Evaluation Of Corporate-Executives , 1986 .

[44]  S. R. Jammalamadaka,et al.  Against the Gods: The Remarkable Story of Risk , 1999 .

[45]  Pramodita Sharma,et al.  Book Reviews: Managing for the Long Run: Lessons in Competitive Advantage from Great Family Businesses , 2005 .

[46]  Kent D. Miller,et al.  Strategic Risk and Corporate Performance: an Analysis of Alternative Risk Measures , 1990 .

[47]  Pramodita Sharma,et al.  Strategic Management of the Family Business: Past Research and Future Challenges , 1997 .

[48]  Kenneth S. Chapman,et al.  Risk tolerance and asset allocation for investors nearing retirement , 2000 .

[49]  J. Berman,et al.  Which industries are sensitive to business cycles? , 1997, Monthly labor review.

[50]  Jeffery Abarbanell,et al.  Is the Us Stock Market Myopic? , 2000 .

[51]  Matthew Richardson,et al.  Industry Returns and the Fisher Effect , 1994 .

[52]  James P. Walsh,et al.  On the Efficiency of Internal and External Corporate Control Mechanisms , 1990 .

[53]  I. MacMillan,et al.  A unified systems perspective of family firm performance , 2003 .

[54]  P. Poutziouris The Views of Family Companies on Venture Capital: Empirical Evidence from the UK Small to Medium-Size Enterprising Economy: , 2001 .

[55]  Aljoša Valentinčič,et al.  The Term Structure of Implicit Discount Rates in Security Valuation , 2005 .

[56]  E. Fama,et al.  Organizational Forms and Investment Decisions , 1985, A Theory of the Firm.

[57]  Albert A. Cannella,et al.  Succession as A Sociopolitical Process: Internal Impediments to Outsider Selection , 1993 .

[58]  S. Satchell,et al.  Testing for Short Termism in the UK Stock Market: A Comment , 1995 .

[59]  Min Chen Asian Management Systems: Chinese, Japanese and Korean Styles of Business , 1995 .

[60]  R. C. Merton,et al.  AN INTERTEMPORAL CAPITAL ASSET PRICING MODEL , 1973 .

[61]  Andreas Hornstein,et al.  The Business Cycle and Industry Comovement , 2000 .

[62]  F. Black Capital Market Equilibrium with Restricted Borrowing , 1972 .