Patronage, Reputation and Common Agency Contracting in the Scientific Revolution: From Keeping 'Nature's Secrets' to the Institutionalization of 'Open Science'

This essay examines the economics of patronage in the production of knowledge and its influence upon the historical formation of key elements in the ethos and organizational structure of publicly funded open science. The emergence during the late sixteenth and early seventeenth centuries of the idea and practice of “open science" was a distinctive and vital organizational aspect of the Scientific Revolution. It represented a break from the previously dominant ethos of secrecy in the pursuit of Nature’s Secrets, to a new set of norms, incentives, and organizational structures that reinforced scientific researchers' commitments to rapid disclosure of new knowledge. The rise of “cooperative rivalries” in the revelation of new knowledge, is seen as a functional response to heightened asymmetric information problems posed for the Renaissance system of court-patronage of the arts and sciences; pre-existing informational asymmetries had been exacerbated by the claims of mathematicians and the increasing practical reliance upon new mathematical techniques in a variety of “contexts of application.” Reputational competition among Europe’s noble patrons motivated much of their efforts to attract to their courts the most prestigious natural philosophers, was no less crucial in the workings of that system than was the concern among their would-be clients to raise their peer-based reputational status. In late Renaissance Europe, the feudal legacy of fragmented political authority had resulted in relations between noble patrons and their savant-clients that resembled the situation modern economists describe as "common agency contracting in substitutes" -- competition among incompletely informed principals for the dedicated services of multiple agents. These conditions tended to result in more favorable contract terms (especially with regard to autonomy and financial support) for the agent-client members of the nascent scientific communities. This left the new scientists better positioned to retain larger information rents on their specialized knowledge, which in turn tended to encourage entry into the emerging disciplines. They also were thereby enabled collectively to develop a stronger degree of professional autonomy for their programs of inquiry within increasingly specialized and formal scientific academies which, during the latter seventeenth century, attracted the patronage of rival absolutist States in Western Europe.

[1]  G. Sarton Appreciation of Ancient and Medieval Science During the Renaissance, 1450-1600 , 1955 .

[2]  Partha Dasgupta,et al.  Information Disclosure and the Economics of Science and Technology , 1987 .

[3]  R. Nelson The Simple Economics of Basic Scientific Research , 1959, Journal of Political Economy.

[4]  Joel Mokyr,et al.  The Lever of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic Progress , 1991 .

[5]  Oliver Grant,et al.  The Diffusion of the Herringbone Parlour: A Case Study in the History of Agricultural Technology , 1998 .

[6]  Norman Kaplan,et al.  The Sociology of Science: Theoretical and Empirical Investigations , 1974 .

[7]  Paul A. David,et al.  General Purpose Technologies and Surges in Productivity: Historical Reflections on the Future of the ICT Revolution , 1999 .

[8]  R. Westfall Science and Patronage: Galileo and the Telescope , 1985, Isis.

[9]  Carl B. Boyer,et al.  A History of Mathematics. , 1993 .

[10]  K. Arrow Uncertainty and the welfare economics of medical care. 1963. , 2004, Bulletin of the World Health Organization.

[11]  M. M. Postan,et al.  The Cambridge Economic History of Europe. Volume III. Economic Organization and Policies in the Middle Ages , 1964 .

[12]  M. Shank Essay Review: Galileo's Day in Court: Galileo, Courtier: The Practice of Science in the Culture of Absolutism , 1994 .

[13]  M. Hollingsworth Patronage in sixteenth-century Italy , 1996 .

[14]  Carl Shapiro,et al.  Navigating the Patent Thicket: Cross Licenses, Patent Pools, and Standard Setting , 2000, Innovation Policy and the Economy.

[15]  Robert P. Merges,et al.  From Medieval Guilds to Open Source Software: Informal Norms, Appropriability Institutions, and Innovation , 2004 .

[16]  P. David Path Dependence, its Critics, and the Quest for ‘Historical Economics’ , 2005 .

[17]  T. H.,et al.  The Role of Scientific Societies in the Seventeenth Century , 1928, Nature.

[18]  Mario Biagioli,et al.  The Social Status of Italian Mathematicians, 1450–1600 , 1989 .

[19]  J. Tirole,et al.  Efficient Patent Pools , 2002 .

[20]  Lode Vereeck the economics of science and scholarship : an analysis of the Althoff system , 1993 .

[21]  Paul A. David,et al.  The Evolutionary Foundations of Economics: Path dependence in economic processes: implications for policy analysis in dynamical system contexts , 2005 .

[22]  Bertrand Gille,et al.  Engineers of the Renaissance , 1966 .

[23]  Paul A. David,et al.  FROM MARKET MAGIC TO CALYPSO SCIENCE POLICY A Review of Terence Kealey's The Economic Laws of Scientific Research , 1997 .

[24]  W. Skeat Early english text society , 1867 .

[25]  P. David,et al.  Towards Institutional Infrastructures for e-Science: The Scope of the Challenge , 2003 .

[26]  Joel Mokyr,et al.  The Lever of Riches: Technological Creativity and Economic Progress. , 1991 .

[27]  Henry Guerlac,et al.  A History of Magic and Experimental Science , 1905 .

[28]  Patrick Suppes,et al.  Institute for Mathematical Studies in the Social Sciences , 1969 .

[29]  P. David,et al.  Early Twentieth Century Productivity Growth Dynamics: An Inquiry into the Economic History of "Our Ignorance" , 1999 .

[30]  Simon Schaffer,et al.  Never at rest. A biography of Isaac Newton , 1981, Medical History.

[31]  L. Brunt What was the Effect of New Crops in the Agricultural Revolution ? Evidence from an Arbitrage Model of Crop Rotation , 2004 .

[32]  K. Arrow Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention , 1962 .

[33]  Oconnor,et al.  The MacTutor History of Mathematics Archive , 2001 .

[34]  Michael Biggs,et al.  Positive feedback in collective mobilization: The American strike wave of 1886 , 2001 .

[35]  Richard G. Olson,et al.  The Mathematicians' Apprenticeship: Science, Universities and Society in England, 1560-1640 , 1985 .

[36]  C. Weare The making of economic policy: A transaction‐cost politics perspective , 1998 .

[37]  Aldo Geuna,et al.  The Economics of Knowledge Production , 1999 .

[38]  Martha Ornstein Bronfenbrenner,et al.  The rôle of scientific societies in the seventeenth century , 1928 .

[39]  Chrisotphe Lecuyer Academic Science and Technology in the Service of Industry: MIT Creates a "Permeable" Engineering School , 1998 .

[40]  D. Guston,et al.  The Fragile Contract: University Science and the Federal Government , 1994 .

[41]  A. Wolf A History of Magic and Experimental Science , 1941, Nature.

[42]  John Walsh,et al.  Knowledge Accumulation and Industry Evolution: The effects of research tool patents and licensing on biomedical innovation , 2006 .

[43]  Paul A. David,et al.  Positive Feedback and Research Productivity in Science: Reopening Another Black Box , 1994 .

[44]  Paul A. David,et al.  Technology adoption, learning spillovers, and the optimal duration of patent-based monopolies , 1992 .

[45]  Catherine Westfall,et al.  Big Science: The Growth of Large-Scale Research ed. by Peter Galison, Bruce Hevly (review) , 1992, Technology and Culture.

[46]  Joseph Ben-David,et al.  Scientific Growth: Essays on the Social Organization and Ethos of Science , 1990 .

[47]  A. Crockett Discussion Papers in Economic and Social History Variations in Churchgoing Rates in England in 1851: Supply-side Deficiency or Demand-led Decline? , 2022 .

[48]  M. Hunter,et al.  Science and Society in Restoration England , 1981 .

[49]  Liam Brunt,et al.  Discussion Papers in Economic and Social History Estimating English Wheat Production in the Industrial Revolution University of Oxford Discussion Papers in Economic and Social History Estimating English Wheat Production in the Industrial Revolution 1 , 2022 .

[50]  M. Hollingsworth Patronage and Innovation in Architecture , 1998 .

[51]  Galileo Galilei,et al.  Discoveries and opinions of Galileo , 1957 .

[52]  G. Speight Who Bought the Inter-War Semi? The Socio-Economic Characteristics of New-House Buyers in the 1930s , 2000 .

[53]  M. Biagioli Replication or Monopoly? The Economies of Invention and Discovery in Galileo's Observations of 1610 , 2000, Science in Context.

[54]  Fred S. Michael,et al.  Mersenne and the learning of the schools , 1990 .

[55]  Bruce L. R. Smith,et al.  American Science Policy Since World War II , 1990 .

[56]  Daniel R. Headrick,et al.  When Information Came of Age: Technologies of Knowledge in the Age of Reason and Revolution, 1700-1850 , 2000 .

[57]  W. Eamon,et al.  Science and the Secrets of Nature: Books of Secrets in Medieval and Early Modern Culture. , 1995 .

[58]  J. Riley,et al.  The Analytics of Uncertainty and Information- An Expository Survey , 1979 .

[59]  Richard S. Westfall Never at Rest: A Biography of Isaac Newton , 1980 .

[60]  J. Ziman Pipers and Tunes in Science. (Book Reviews: Prometheus Bound. Science in a Dynamic Steady State.) , 2005 .

[61]  Christopher Freeman,et al.  Technology and the wealth of nations : the dynamics of constructed advantage , 1993 .

[62]  Nathan Rosenberg,et al.  Inside the black box , 1983 .

[63]  D. North Institutions, institutional change and economic performance: Cambridge university press. , 1990 .

[64]  W. C. Boesman Analysis of Ten Selected Science and Technology Policy Studies , 1997 .

[65]  B. J. Dobbs Essay Review: Newton as Alchemist: The Foundations of Newton's Alchemy, or “The Hunting of the Greene Lyon” , 1977 .

[66]  D. North Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance: Economic performance , 1990 .

[67]  P. Burke Occult and scientific mentalities in the Renaissance , 1986 .

[68]  A. Offer Discussion Papers in Economic and Social History , 2000 .

[69]  Antonia Taddei,et al.  London Clubs in the Late Nineteenth Century , 1999 .

[70]  J. Vienne The foundations of Newton's alchemy or “The hunting of the greene lyon” , 1977, Medical History.

[71]  David Stead,et al.  An Arduous and Unprofitable Undertaking: The Enclosure of Stanton Harcourt, Oxfordshire , 1998 .

[72]  Gordon Leff,et al.  Paris and Oxford Universities in the thirteenth and fourteenth centuries: An institutional and intellectual history , 1975 .

[73]  D. Boorstin,et al.  The Discoverers: A History of Man’s Search to Know His World and Himself by Daniel J. Boorstin (review) , 2023 .

[74]  R. Merton,et al.  The Sociology of Science: Theoretical and Empirical Investigations , 1975, Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion.

[75]  N. Rosenberg,et al.  How the West Grew Rich: The Economic Transforma-tion of the Industrial World , 1987 .

[76]  P. David,et al.  The research network and the new economics of science: from metaphors to organisational behaviours , 1998 .

[77]  Paul A. David Science reorganized? : Post-modern visions of research and the curse of success , 1996 .

[78]  Charles Webster,et al.  Samuel Hartlib and the advancement of learning , 1971 .

[79]  M. Biagioli Galileo's System of Patronage , 1990 .

[80]  B. Vickers Occult and scientific mentalities in the Renaissance , 1984 .

[81]  Paula E. Stephan The Economics of Science , 1996 .

[82]  G. Sarton "The appreciation of ancient and medieval science during the Renaissance 1450-1600", George Sarton, Philadelphia 1955 : [recenzja] / M. B.-N. , 1955 .

[83]  Christopher Freeman,et al.  Prometheus Bound: science in a dynamic steady state , 1995, European Review.

[84]  C. Ronan The lord of uraniborg: a biography of Tycho Brahe , 1991 .

[85]  R. Noll,et al.  Privatizing public research. , 1994, Scientific American.

[86]  Peter Urbach,et al.  Novum organum : with other parts of The great instauration , 1994 .

[87]  A. Arora,et al.  Reputation and Competence in Publicly Funded Science: Estimating the Effects on Research Group Productivity , 1998 .

[88]  R. Hahn The anatomy of a scientific institution: The Paris Academy of Sciences, 1666-1803 , 1971 .

[89]  H. L. Clark,et al.  Patronage and institutions: science, technology and medicine at the European court, 1500–1750 , 1993, Medical History.

[90]  A. Stroup A Company of Scientists: Botany, Patronage, and Community at the Seventeenth-Century Parisian Royal Academy of Sciences , 1990 .

[91]  G. R. Feiwel Arrow and the ascent of modern economic theory , 1987 .

[92]  Mario Biagioli,et al.  Galileo, Courtier: The Practice of Science in the Culture of Absolutism , 1994 .

[93]  Paul A. David,et al.  Common Agency Contracting and the Emergence of "Open Science" Institutions , 1998 .

[94]  P. Temin A Market Economy in the Early Roman Empire* , 2001, Journal of Roman Studies.

[95]  Harcourt Brown Scientific organizations in seventeenth century France (1620-1680) , 1935 .

[96]  W. Eamon,et al.  From the secrets of nature to public knowledge: The origins of the concept of openness in science , 1985 .

[97]  A. Diamond Economics of Science , 2008 .

[98]  J. Needham,et al.  The Grand Titration , 1971, The Journal of Asian Studies.

[99]  L. Brunt,et al.  “ Where There ’ s Muck , There ’ s Brass ” The Market for Manure in the Industrial Revolution , 2000 .

[100]  T. Data,et al.  The Economic Logic of “Open Science” and the Balance between Private Property Rights and the Public Domain in Scientific Data and Information: A Primer , 2003 .

[101]  Richard A. Goldthwaite Wealth and the demand for art in Italy, 1300-1600 , 1993 .

[102]  P. David,et al.  Toward a new economics of science , 1994 .

[103]  R. Strong Art and power : Renaissance festivals, 1450-1650 , 1986 .

[104]  J. Mcclellan Science reorganized: Scientific societies in the eighteenth century , 1985 .

[105]  David Lamb,et al.  Multiple discovery: The pattern of scientific progress , 1984 .

[106]  D. Foray Economics of knowledge , 2004 .

[107]  D. Landes The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some Are So Rich and Some So Poor , 1995 .

[108]  J. O'Neill Property in Science and the Market , 1990 .

[109]  D. Lux,et al.  Patronage and royal science in seventeenth-century France : the Académie de physique in Caen , 1991 .

[110]  Paul A. David,et al.  Communication Norms and the Collective Cognitive Performance of "Invisible Colleges". , 1998 .

[111]  Alexander Keller Mathematics, mechanics and the origins of the culture of mechanical invention , 1985 .

[112]  Blaise Cronin,et al.  : Empowering Technology: Implementing a U.S. Strategy , 1995 .

[113]  L. S. King The Anatomy of a Scientific Institution: The Paris Academy of Sciences, 1666-1803 , 1972 .

[114]  W. Wians The Beginnings of Western Science: The European Scientific Tradition in Philosophical, Religious, and Institutional Context, 600 B.C. to A.D. 1450 , 1995 .

[115]  R. Briggs THE ACADÉMIE ROYALE DES SCIENCES AND THE PURSUIT OF UTILITY , 1991 .

[116]  S. Epstein Craft Guilds, Apprenticeship, and Technological Change in Preindustrial Europe , 1998, The Journal of Economic History.

[117]  M. West State Intervention in English Education, 1833-1891: A Public Goods and Agency Approach , 2000 .