The provision of public goods under alternative electoral incentives

Politicians who care about the spoils of office may underprovide a public good because its benefits cannot be targeted to voters as easily as pork-barrel spending. We compare a winner-take-all system--where all the spoils go to the winner--to a proportional system--where the spoils of office are split among candidates proportionally to their share of the vote. In a winner-take-all system the public good is provided less often than in a proportional system when the public good is particularly desirable. We then consider the electoral college system and show that it is particularly subject to this inefficiency.

[1]  Steven J. Brams,et al.  The 3/2's Rule in Presidential Campaigning , 1974, American Political Science Review.

[2]  Kenneth A. Shepsle,et al.  The Political Economy of Benefits and Costs: A Neoclassical Approach to Distributive Politics , 1981, Journal of Political Economy.

[3]  G. Tabellini,et al.  Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy , 2000 .

[4]  H. Bowen,et al.  The Interpretation of Voting in the Allocation of Economic Resources , 1943 .

[5]  H. Rosenthal,et al.  Are legislators ideologues or the agents of constituents , 1996 .

[6]  R. Marimon,et al.  The Economics of Split-Ticket Voting in Representative Democracies , 1997 .

[7]  J. Weibull,et al.  Balanced-budget redistribution as the outcome of political competition , 1987 .

[8]  David R. Mayhew Congress: The Electoral Connection , 1975 .

[9]  D. P. Baron,et al.  Majoritarian Incentives, Pork Barrel Programs, and Procedural Control , 1991 .

[10]  M. Osborne,et al.  A Model of Political Competition with Citizen-Candidates , 1996 .

[11]  James M. Buchanan and Gordon Tullock The Calculus of Consent , 1962 .

[12]  Stephen Morris,et al.  On the Form of Transfers to Special Interests , 1995, Journal of Political Economy.

[13]  J. Snyder Election Goals and the Allocation of Campaign Resources , 1989 .

[14]  Torsten Persson,et al.  Political Economics and Public Finance , 1999 .

[15]  Stephen Coate,et al.  An Economic Model of Representative Democracy , 1997 .

[16]  Torsten Persson,et al.  The Size and the Scope of Government: Comparative Politics with Rational Politicians , 1998 .

[17]  Torsten Persson,et al.  Comparative Politics and Public Finance , 1997, Journal of Political Economy.

[18]  A. Lizzeri,et al.  Provision of Public Goods Under Alternative Electral Incentives , 1999 .

[19]  J. Banks,et al.  Elections, Coalitions, and Legislative Outcomes , 1988, American Political Science Review.

[20]  G. Tabellini,et al.  Federal Fiscal Constitutions: Risk Sharing and Redistribution , 1996, Journal of Political Economy.

[21]  Timothy Besley,et al.  Sources of Inefficiency in a Representative Democracy: A Dynamic Analysis , 1998 .

[22]  A. Lizzeri Budget de?cits and redistributive politics , 1999 .

[23]  G. Tabellini,et al.  Federal Fiscal Constitutions: Risk Sharing and Moral Hazard , 1996 .

[24]  Daniel Diermeier,et al.  Dynamics of Parliamentary Systems: Selections, Governments, and Parliaments , 1988 .

[25]  G. Scofield,et al.  The calculus of consent. , 1990, The Hastings Center report.

[26]  James A. Robinson,et al.  The Political Economy of Clientelism , 2002 .

[27]  R. Myerson Incentives to Cultivate Favored Minorities Under Alternative Electoral Systems , 1993, American Political Science Review.

[28]  Joseph E. Stiglitz,et al.  Economics of the Public Sector , 1986 .