On the probabilities of correct or incorrect majority preference relations

Abstract. While majority cycles may pose a threat to democratic decision making, actual decisions based inadvertently upon an incorrect majority preference relation may be far more expensive to society. We study majority rule both in a statistical sampling and a Bayesian inference framework. Based on any given paired comparison probabilities or ranking probabilities in a population (i.e., culture) of reference, we derive upper and lower bounds on the probability of a correct or incorrect majority social welfare relation in a random sample (with replacement). We also present upper and lower bounds on the probabilities of majority preference relations in the population given a sample, using Bayesian updating. These bounds permit to map quite precisely the entire picture of possible majority preference relations as well as their probabilities. We illustrate our results using survey data.

[1]  Peter C. Fishburn,et al.  Probabilities of election outcomes for large electorates , 1978 .

[2]  C. Plott,et al.  The Probability of a Cyclical Majority , 1970 .

[3]  Andranik Tangian,et al.  Unlikelihood of Condorcet’s paradox in a large society , 2000, Soc. Choice Welf..

[4]  K. Arrow,et al.  Social Choice and Individual Values , 1951 .

[5]  A. A. J. Marley,et al.  A general concept of majority rule , 2002, Math. Soc. Sci..

[6]  Salvador Barberà,et al.  Falmagne and the Rationalizability of Stochastic Choices in Terms of Random Orderings , 1986 .

[7]  William V. Gehrlein,et al.  Condorcet efficiencies under the maximal culture condition , 1999 .

[8]  B. Grofman,et al.  Approval Voting, Borda Winners, and Condorcet Winners: Evidence From Seven Elections , 1998 .

[9]  Benjamin Radcliff,et al.  Condorcet Winners and the Paradox of Voting: Probability Calculations for Weak Preference Orders , 1995, American Political Science Review.

[10]  Dominique Lepelley,et al.  Scoring Rules, Condorcet Efficiency and Social Homogeneity , 2000 .

[11]  R. Luce,et al.  The Choice Axiom after Twenty Years , 1977 .

[12]  R. Duncan Luce,et al.  Individual Choice Behavior: A Theoretical Analysis , 1979 .

[13]  R. Luce,et al.  Individual Choice Behavior: A Theoretical Analysis. , 1960 .

[14]  J. B. Hill,et al.  Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research Datasets , 1997 .

[15]  David Heckerman,et al.  A Tutorial on Learning with Bayesian Networks , 1998, Learning in Graphical Models.

[16]  Michel Regenwetter,et al.  Choosing subsets: a size-independent probabilistic model and the quest for a social welfare ordering , 1998 .

[17]  L. Thurstone,et al.  A low of comparative judgement , 1927 .

[18]  Peter C. Fishburn,et al.  Effects of abstentions on voting procedures in three‐candidate elections , 1979 .

[19]  Michel Regenwetter,et al.  On the (Sample) Condorcet Efficiency of Majority Rule: An alternative view of majority cycles and social homogeneity , 2002 .

[20]  William V. Gehrlein Condorcet Efficiency of Borda Rule under the Dual Culture Condition , 1999 .

[21]  Adrian Van Deemen,et al.  The Probability of the Paradox of Voting for Weak Preference Orderings , 1999 .

[22]  Helmut Norpoth,et al.  The Parties Come to Order! Dimensions of Preferential Choice in the West German Electorate, 1961–1976 , 1979, American Political Science Review.

[23]  A. Tversky Choice by elimination , 1972 .

[24]  P. Fishburn,et al.  Condorcet's paradox and anonymous preference profiles , 1976 .

[25]  Scott L. Feld,et al.  Ideological Consistency as a Collective Phenomenon , 1988, American Political Science Review.

[26]  S. Berg Paradox of voting under an urn model: The effect of homogeneity , 1985 .

[27]  Barry C. Burden Deterministic and Probabilistic Voting Models , 1997 .

[28]  William V. Gehrlein,et al.  Condorcet efficiency: A preference for indifference , 2001, Soc. Choice Welf..

[29]  Peter C. Fishburn,et al.  Induced binary probabilities and the linear ordering polytope: a status report , 1992 .

[30]  Jean-Claude Falmagne,et al.  A representation theorem for finite random scale systems , 1978 .

[31]  William V. Gehrlein,et al.  Probability calculations for transitivity of the simple majority rule , 1988 .

[32]  John R. Wright,et al.  Voting cycles and the structure of individual preferences , 1987 .

[33]  L. A. Goodman,et al.  Social Choice and Individual Values , 1951 .

[34]  William V. Gehrlein,et al.  The Condorcet efficiency of Borda Rule with anonymous voters , 2001, Math. Soc. Sci..

[35]  B. Grofman,et al.  A stochastic model of preference change and its application to 1992 presidential election panel data , 1999 .

[36]  Michel Regenwetter,et al.  A random utility model for approval voting , 1996 .

[37]  S. Berg,et al.  A note on the paradox of voting: Anonymous preference profiles and May's formula , 1983 .