Short-Run Subsidies and Long-Run Adoption of New Health Products: Evidence from a Field Experiment

Short-run subsidies for health products are common in poor countries. How do they affect long-run adoption? A common fear among development practitioners is that one-off subsidies may negatively affect long-run adoption through reference-dependence: People might anchor around the subsidized price and be unwilling to pay more for the product later. But for experience goods, one-off subsidies could also boost long-run adoption through learning. This paper uses data from a two-stage randomized pricing experiment in Kenya to estimate the relative importance of these effects for a new, improved antimalarial bed net. Reduced form estimates show that a one-time subsidy has a positive impact on willingness to pay a year later inherit. To separately identify the learning and anchoring effects, we estimate a parsimonious experience-good model. Estimation results show a large, positive learning effect but no anchoring. We black then discuss the types of products and the contexts inherit for which these results may apply.

[1]  K. Stowman World health statistics. , 1949, The Milbank Memorial Fund quarterly.

[2]  K. Bagwell,et al.  High and Declining Prices Signal Product Quality , 1991 .

[3]  C. Manski Identification of Endogenous Social Effects: The Reflection Problem , 1993 .

[4]  A. Tversky,et al.  Choice in Context: Tradeoff Contrast and Extremeness Aversion , 1992 .

[5]  A. Tversky,et al.  Choice in Context: Tradeoff Contrast and Extremeness Aversion , 1992 .

[6]  A. Case,et al.  Diffusion as a Learning Process: Evidence from HYV Cotton , 1994 .

[7]  M. Rosenzweig,et al.  Learning by Doing and Learning from Others: Human Capital and Technical Change in Agriculture , 1995, Journal of Political Economy.

[8]  John S. Strauss,et al.  Health nutrition and economic development. , 1998 .

[9]  Lones Smith,et al.  The Optimal Level of Experimentation , 2000 .

[10]  Timothy G. Conley GMM estimation with cross sectional dependence , 1999 .

[11]  Daniel McFadden,et al.  Rationality for Economists? , 1999 .

[12]  Daniel McFadden,et al.  Rationality for Economists , 1999 .

[13]  D. Bergemann,et al.  Experimentation in Markets , 2000 .

[14]  J. Behrman,et al.  How can we measure the causal effects of social networks using observational data? Evidence from the diffusion of family planning and AIDS worries in South Nyanza District, Kenya , 2001 .

[15]  U. d’Alessandro Insecticide treated bed nets to prevent malaria , 2001, BMJ : British Medical Journal.

[16]  Morten I. Lau,et al.  Estimating Individual Discount Rates in Denmark: A Field Experiment , 2002 .

[17]  Imran Rasul,et al.  Social Networks and Technology Adoption in Northern Mozambique , 2002 .

[18]  D. Ariely,et al.  “Coherent Arbitrariness”: Stable Demand Curves Without Stable Preferences , 2003 .

[19]  Z. Bhutta,et al.  How many child deaths can we prevent this year? , 2003, The Lancet.

[20]  Jean-Pierre Habicht,et al.  Iron deficiency and the well-being of older adults: Early results from a randomized nutrition intervention , 2003 .

[21]  Robert E Black,et al.  Where and why are 10 million children dying every year? , 2003, The Lancet.

[22]  M. Kolczak,et al.  Community-wide effects of permethrin-treated bed nets on child mortality and malaria morbidity in western Kenya. , 2003, The American journal of tropical medicine and hygiene.

[23]  Patricia M. Kristjanson,et al.  Geographic Dimensions of Well-Being in Kenya: Where are the Poor? From Districts to Locations (Volume One) , 2003 .

[24]  C. Lengeler,et al.  Insecticide-treated bed nets and curtains for preventing malaria. , 2004, The Cochrane database of systematic reviews.

[25]  M. Kremer,et al.  The Illusion of Sustainability , 2004 .

[26]  Kaivan Munshi Social learning in a heterogeneous population: technology diffusion in the Indian Green Revolution , 2004 .

[27]  M. Rabin,et al.  A Model of Reference-Dependent Preferences , 2006 .

[28]  R. Cooper,et al.  The end of poverty: economic possibilities for our time. , 2008, European journal of dental education : official journal of the Association for Dental Education in Europe.

[29]  Giuseppe Moscarini,et al.  Job Matching and the Wage Distribution , 2005 .

[30]  George Loewenstein,et al.  Mistake #37: The Effect of Previously Encountered Prices on Current Housing Demand , 2006 .

[31]  Dirk Bergemann,et al.  Dynamic Pricing of New Experience Goods , 2006, Journal of Political Economy.

[32]  Kaivan Munshi,et al.  Social norms and the fertility transition , 2006 .

[33]  J. Bresee,et al.  Point-of-use water treatment and use among mothers in Malawi. , 2007, Emerging infectious diseases.

[34]  S. P. Kachur,et al.  Preventing Childhood Malaria in Africa by Protecting Adults from Mosquitoes with Insecticide-Treated Nets , 2007, PLoS medicine.

[35]  J. Bresee,et al.  Point-of-Use Water Treatment and Use among Mothers in Malawi , 2007, Emerging Infectious Diseases.

[36]  Jesse M. Shapiro,et al.  Can Higher Prices Stimulate Product Use? Evidence from a Field Experiment in Zambia , 2010 .

[37]  P. Dupas,et al.  Free Distribution or Cost-Sharing? Evidence from a Randomized Malaria Prevention Experiment , 2007 .

[38]  J. Sachs,et al.  THE END OF POVERTY: Economic Possibilities for Our Time , 2005 .

[39]  M. Kremer,et al.  Trickle down: Diffusion of chlorine for drinking water treatment in Kenya , 2008 .

[40]  E. Oster,et al.  Determinants of Technology Adoption: Private Value and Peer Effects in Menstrual Cup Take-Up , 2009 .

[41]  P. Dupas,et al.  What Matters (and What Does Not) in Households' Decision to Invest in Malaria Prevention? , 2009, The American economic review.

[42]  Jonathan Robinson,et al.  Nudging Farmers to Use Fertilizer: Theory and Experimental Evidence from Kenya , 2009 .

[43]  Ori Heffetz,et al.  How Large are Non-Budget-Constraint Effects of Prices on Demand? , 2009 .

[44]  Timothy G. Conley,et al.  Learning About a New Technology: Pineapple in Ghana , 2010 .

[45]  M. Rosenzweig,et al.  Microeconomics of Technology Adoption. , 2010, Annual review of economics.

[46]  Awori J. Hayanga The End of Poverty: Economic Possibilities for Our Time , 2010 .

[47]  Erik Snowberg,et al.  Selective Trials: A Principal-Agent Approach to Randomized Controlled Experiments , 2010 .

[48]  E. Oster,et al.  DETERMINANTS OF TECHNOLOGY ADOPTION: PEER EFFECTS IN MENSTRUAL CUP TAKE-UP , 2012 .

[49]  Jamie Perin,et al.  Global, regional, and national causes of child mortality: an updated systematic analysis for 2010 with time trends since 2000 , 2012, The Lancet.

[50]  P. Dupas,et al.  PRICE SUBSIDIES, DIAGNOSTIC TESTS, AND TARGETING OF MALARIA TREATMENT: EVIDENCE FROM A RANDOMIZED CONTROLLED TRIAL , 2011 .

[51]  Achyuta Adhvaryu,et al.  Learning, Misallocation, and Technology Adoption: Evidence from New Malaria Therapy in Tanzania. , 2014, The Review of economic studies.

[52]  Aprajit Mahajan,et al.  Micro-Loans, Insecticide-Treated Bednets and Malaria: Evidence from a Randomized Controlled Trial in Orissa (India) , 2011, The American economic review.

[53]  Simone Schaner,et al.  Web Appendix : Do Opposites Detract ? Intrahousehold Preference Heterogeneity and Inefficient Strategic Savings , 2014 .