Evolution of fairness in the one-shot anonymous Ultimatum Game

Classical economic models assume that people are fully rational and selfish, while experiments often point to different conclusions. A canonical example is the Ultimatum Game: one player proposes a division of a sum of money between herself and a second player, who either accepts or rejects. Based on rational self-interest, responders should accept any nonzero offer and proposers should offer the smallest possible amount. Traditional, deterministic models of evolutionary game theory agree: in the one-shot anonymous Ultimatum Game, natural selection favors low offers and demands. Experiments instead show a preference for fairness: often responders reject low offers and proposers make higher offers than needed to avoid rejection. Here we show that using stochastic evolutionary game theory, where agents make mistakes when judging the payoffs and strategies of others, natural selection favors fairness. Across a range of parameters, the average strategy matches the observed behavior: proposers offer between 30% and 50%, and responders demand between 25% and 40%. Rejecting low offers increases relative payoff in pairwise competition between two strategies and is favored when selection is sufficiently weak. Offering more than you demand increases payoff when many strategies are present simultaneously and is favored when mutation is sufficiently high. We also perform a behavioral experiment and find empirical support for these theoretical findings: uncertainty about the success of others is associated with higher demands and offers; and inconsistency in the behavior of others is associated with higher offers but not predictive of demands. In an uncertain world, fairness finishes first.

[1]  N. Christakis,et al.  Bias and asymmetric loss in expert forecasts: a study of physician prognostic behavior with respect to patient survival. , 2008, Journal of health economics.

[2]  J M Smith,et al.  Evolution and the theory of games , 1976 .

[3]  Colin Camerer Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction , 2003 .

[4]  Ken Binmore,et al.  Learning to be imperfect: The ultimatum game , 1995 .

[5]  Arne Traulsen,et al.  Exploration dynamics in evolutionary games , 2009, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[6]  M. Nowak,et al.  Evolutionary Dynamics of Biological Games , 2004, Science.

[7]  Josef Hofbauer,et al.  Evolutionary Games and Population Dynamics , 1998 .

[8]  Klaus M. Schmidt,et al.  A Theory of Fairness, Competition, and Cooperation , 1999 .

[9]  David G. Rand,et al.  Currency value moderates equity preference among young children , 2010 .

[10]  Matthew D. Lieberman,et al.  The Sunny Side of Fairness , 2008, Psychological science.

[11]  S. Zamir,et al.  Bargaining and Market Behavior in Jerusalem, Ljubljana, Pittsburgh, and Tokyo: An Experimental Study , 1991 .

[12]  David G. Rand,et al.  The online laboratory: conducting experiments in a real labor market , 2010, ArXiv.

[13]  Haijin Lin,et al.  Using Experimental Data to Model Bargaining Behavior in Ultimatum Games , 2001 .

[14]  J. Henrich,et al.  Costly Punishment Across Human Societies , 2006, Science.

[15]  Tore Ellingsen,et al.  The Evolution of Bargaining Behavior , 1997 .

[16]  M. Nowak,et al.  Mutation-selection equilibrium in games with mixed strategies. , 2009, Journal of theoretical biology.

[17]  C. Darwin The Descent of Man and Selection in Relation to Sex: INDEX , 1871 .

[18]  H. Ohtsuki Stochastic evolutionary dynamics of bimatrix games. , 2010, Journal of theoretical biology.

[19]  Laurent Lehmann,et al.  Inclusive fitness theory and eusociality , 2011, Nature.

[20]  R. Lewontin Evolution and the theory of games. , 1961, Journal of theoretical biology.

[21]  Madan M. Pillutla,et al.  Unfairness, Anger, and Spite: Emotional Rejections of Ultimatum Offers , 1996 .

[22]  David G. Rand,et al.  Dynamic social networks promote cooperation in experiments with humans , 2011, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[23]  David G. Rand,et al.  Strategic Self-Interest Can Explain Seemingly 'Fair' Offers in the Ultimatum Game , 2013 .

[24]  James H. Fowler,et al.  Egalitarian motives in humans , 2007, Nature.

[25]  Yoh Iwasa,et al.  The leading eight: social norms that can maintain cooperation by indirect reciprocity. , 2006, Journal of theoretical biology.

[26]  C. Hauert,et al.  Via Freedom to Coercion: The Emergence of Costly Punishment , 2007, Science.

[27]  P. Zak,et al.  Oxytocin Increases Generosity in Humans , 2007, PloS one.

[28]  H. Young An Evolutionary Model of Bargaining , 1993 .

[29]  Arne Traulsen,et al.  Freedom, enforcement, and the social dilemma of strong altruism , 2010 .

[30]  Panagiotis G. Ipeirotis,et al.  Running Experiments on Amazon Mechanical Turk , 2010, Judgment and Decision Making.

[31]  Frederick Mosteller,et al.  Stochastic Models for Learning , 1956 .

[32]  David G. Rand,et al.  Stochastic evolutionary dynamics resolve the Traveler's Dilemma. , 2012, Journal of theoretical biology.

[33]  M. Johannesson,et al.  Heritability of ultimatum game responder behavior , 2007, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[34]  P J Richerson,et al.  Group selection among alternative evolutionarily stable strategies. , 1990, Journal of theoretical biology.

[35]  P. Blake,et al.  “I had so much it didn’t seem fair”: Eight-year-olds reject two forms of inequity , 2011, Cognition.

[36]  Dominic D. P. Johnson,et al.  The evolution of overconfidence , 2009, Nature.

[37]  J. Hofbauer,et al.  Adaptive dynamics and evolutionary stability , 1990 .

[38]  James H. Fowler,et al.  Habitual Voting and Behavioral Turnout , 2006, The Journal of Politics.

[39]  P. Taylor,et al.  Evolutionarily Stable Strategies and Game Dynamics , 1978 .

[40]  Colin Camerer,et al.  “Economic man” in cross-cultural perspective: Behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies , 2005, Behavioral and Brain Sciences.

[41]  David G. Rand,et al.  The promise of Mechanical Turk: how online labor markets can help theorists run behavioral experiments. , 2012, Journal of theoretical biology.

[42]  David G. Rand,et al.  Economic Games on the Internet: The Effect of $1 Stakes , 2011, PloS one.

[43]  R. Larrick,et al.  The Claiming Effect: Why Players Are More Generous in Social Dilemmas Than in Ultimatum Games , 1997 .

[44]  B. Rockenbach,et al.  Egalitarianism in young children , 2008, Nature.

[45]  A. Shaw,et al.  Children discard a resource to avoid inequity. , 2012, Journal of experimental psychology. General.

[46]  Á. Pascual-Leone,et al.  Diminishing Reciprocal Fairness by Disrupting the Right Prefrontal Cortex , 2006, Science.

[47]  Jörgen W. Weibull,et al.  Evolutionary Game Theory , 1996 .

[48]  W. Güth,et al.  An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining , 1982 .

[49]  Drew Fudenberg,et al.  Imitation Processes with Small Mutations , 2004, J. Econ. Theory.

[50]  Steffen Huck,et al.  The Indirect Evolutionary Approach to Explaining Fair Allocations , 1999 .

[51]  M. Nowak,et al.  Evolution of indirect reciprocity , 2005, Nature.

[52]  R. Boyd,et al.  In Search of Homo Economicus: Behavioral Experiments in 15 Small- Scale Societies , 2001 .

[53]  Daniel Kahneman,et al.  Fairness and the Assumptions of Economics , 1986 .

[54]  M. Nowak,et al.  Fairness versus reason in the ultimatum game. , 2000, Science.

[55]  P. Moran,et al.  The statistical processes of evolutionary theory. , 1963 .

[56]  ปิยดา สมบัติวัฒนา Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction , 2013 .

[57]  David G. Rand,et al.  Spontaneous giving and calculated greed , 2012, Nature.

[58]  M. Nowak,et al.  The evolution of eusociality , 2010, Nature.

[59]  S. Solnick Gender differences in the ultimatum game , 2001 .

[60]  Martin A. Nowak,et al.  Public Goods With Punishment and Abstaining in Finite and Infinite Populations , 2008, Biological theory.

[61]  M. Nowak,et al.  Evolution of cooperation by multilevel selection. , 2006, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America.

[62]  U. Witt Explaining process and change : approaches to evolutionary economics , 1992 .

[63]  Martin A. Nowak,et al.  Information, Irrationality and the Evolution of Trust , 2012 .

[64]  D. Fudenberg,et al.  Emergence of cooperation and evolutionary stability in finite populations , 2004, Nature.

[65]  Michael D. Buhrmester,et al.  Amazon's Mechanical Turk , 2011, Perspectives on psychological science : a journal of the Association for Psychological Science.

[66]  Siddharth Suri,et al.  Conducting behavioral research on Amazon’s Mechanical Turk , 2010, Behavior research methods.

[67]  David G. Rand,et al.  The evolution of antisocial punishment in optional public goods games. , 2011, Nature communications.

[68]  M. Nowak,et al.  A generalized adaptive dynamics framework can describe the evolutionary Ultimatum Game. , 2001, Journal of theoretical biology.

[69]  David G. Rand,et al.  The value of reputation , 2012, Journal of The Royal Society Interface.

[70]  David G. Rand,et al.  Evolutionary dynamics in finite populations can explain the full range of cooperative behaviors observed in the centipede game. , 2012, Journal of theoretical biology.

[71]  M. Nowak,et al.  Evolution of indirect reciprocity by image scoring , 1998, Nature.

[72]  J. Keith Murnighan,et al.  An experimental investigation of ultimatum games: information, fairness, expectations, and lowest acceptable offers , 1995 .

[73]  H. Ohtsuki,et al.  Mutation-selection equilibrium in games with multiple strategies. , 2008, Journal of theoretical biology.

[74]  W. Ewens Mathematical Population Genetics : I. Theoretical Introduction , 2004 .

[75]  K Sigmund,et al.  A note on evolutionary stable strategies and game dynamics. , 1979, Journal of theoretical biology.

[76]  Jonathan D. Cohen,et al.  The Neural Basis of Economic Decision-Making in the Ultimatum Game , 2003, Science.

[77]  Michihiro Kandori Social Norms and Community Enforcement , 1992 .

[78]  A. Simmons,et al.  Neural basis of egalitarian behavior , 2012, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.