Lies, damned lies, and political campaigns

Abstract Despite a pervasive presence in politics, lying has not traditionally played a role in formal models of elections. In this paper we develop a model that allows candidates in the campaign stage to misrepresent their policy intentions if elected to office, and in which the willingness to lie varies across candidates. We find that candidates more willing to lie are favored, but that this advantage is limited by the electoral mechanism and to such an extent that more honest candidates win a significant fraction of elections. Most notably, the possibility that some candidates lie more than others affects the behavior of all candidates, changing the nature of political campaigns in an empirically consistent manner. This effect also implies that misleading conclusions will be drawn if homogeneous candidate honesty is assumed.

[1]  J. Sobel,et al.  Equilibrium Selection in Signaling Games , 1987 .

[2]  John Duggan,et al.  A dynamic model of democratic elections in multidimensional policy spaces , 2008 .

[3]  G. Tabellini,et al.  Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy , 2000 .

[4]  Joseph E. Harrington,et al.  The Equilibrium Level of Rigidity in a Hierarchy , 1999 .

[5]  Jr. Joseph E. Harrington,et al.  Rigidity of Social Systems , 1999 .

[6]  David M. Kreps,et al.  Signaling Games and Stable Equilibria , 1987 .

[7]  R. Calvert Robustness of the Multidimensional Voting Model: Candidate Motivations, Uncertainty, and Convergence* , 1985 .

[8]  Partially Informative Signaling , 1999 .

[9]  A. Downs An Economic Theory of Democracy , 1957 .

[10]  H. Hotelling Stability in Competition , 1929 .

[11]  J. Harrington Progressive Ambition Electoral Selection and the Creation of Ideologues , 2000 .

[12]  D. Black On the Rationale of Group Decision-making , 1948, Journal of Political Economy.

[13]  M.Daniel Bernhardt,et al.  Candidate reputations and the 'incumbency effect' , 1985 .

[14]  Donald E. Stokes,et al.  Spatial Models of Party Competition , 1963, American Political Science Review.

[15]  Joseph E. Harrington,et al.  Economic Policy, Economic Performance, and Elections , 1993 .

[16]  Joseph E. Harrington,et al.  A Theory of Rigid Extremists and Flexible Moderates with an Application to the U.S. Congress , 2000 .

[17]  O. Swank Partisan Politics, Divided Government, and the Economy , 1996 .

[18]  Enriqueta Aragones,et al.  Mixed Equilibrium in a Downsian Model with a Favored Candidate , 2000 .

[19]  Joseph E. Harrington,et al.  The Social Selection of Flexible and Rigid Agents , 1998 .

[20]  R. Barro The control of politicians: An economic model , 1973 .

[21]  Steven D. Levitt,et al.  How Do Senators Vote? Disentangling the Role of Voter Preferences, Party Affiliation, and Senate Ideology , 1996 .

[22]  Dan Bernhardt,et al.  Term limits and pork barrel politics , 2004 .

[23]  D. Wittman Candidate Motivation: A Synthesis of Alternative Theories , 1983, American Political Science Review.

[24]  B. Bernheim,et al.  A Theory of Conformity , 1994, Journal of Political Economy.

[25]  W. Robert Reed A RETROSPECTIVE VOTING MODEL WITH HETEROGENEOUS POLITICIANS , 1994 .

[26]  J. Harrington The Impact of Reelection Pressures on the Fulfillment of Campaign Promises , 1993 .

[27]  Jeffrey S. Banks,et al.  A model of electoral competition with incomplete information , 1990 .

[28]  A. Wildavsky The Goldwater Phenomenon: Purists, Politicians, and the Two-Party System , 1965, The Review of Politics.

[29]  D. Black The theory of committees and elections , 1959 .

[30]  John Duggan,et al.  Repeated Elections with Asymmetric Information , 2000 .

[31]  J. Banks,et al.  Elections, Coalitions, and Legislative Outcomes , 1988, American Political Science Review.

[32]  Tim Groseclose,et al.  A Model of Candidate Location When One Candidate Has a Valence Advantage , 2001 .