Sensitivity, Precision, and Linear Aggregation of Signals for Performance Evaluation

Several accounting and other signals are generally available for the construction of a managerial performance evaluation measure on which an optimal compensation contract is based. The demand for aggregation in evaluating managerial performance arises because reporting all the basic transactions and other nonfinancial information about performance is costly and impracticable (see Ashton [1982], Casey [1978], and Holmstrom and Milgrom [1987]). We identify necessary and sufficient conditions on the joint density function of the signals under which linear aggregation, a simple and commonly employed way to construct a performance evaluation measure, is optimal. This characterization suggests that the linear form of aggregation is optimal for a large class of situations. Focusing on performance measures that are linear aggregates enables us to determine the relative weights on the individual signals in the optimal linear aggregate, since these weights are invariant for all realizations of the signals. We interpret these weights in terms of statistical characteristics (sensitivity and precision) of the joint distribution of the signals.

[1]  Cornelius John Casey The cognitive effect of variation in accounting information load : a study of bank loan officers , 1978 .

[2]  Russell M. Barefield The Effect of Aggregation on Decision Making Success: A Laboratory Study , 1972 .

[3]  J. C. Jaeger An introduction to the Laplace transformation with engineering applications , 1969 .

[4]  J Crank An Introduction to the Laplace Transformation with Engineering Applications , 1961 .

[5]  Bengt Holmstrom,et al.  Moral Hazard in Teams , 1982 .

[6]  Paul R. Milgrom,et al.  AGGREGATION AND LINEARITY IN THE PROVISION OF INTERTEMPORAL INCENTIVES , 1987 .

[7]  D. Widder,et al.  The Laplace Transform , 1943, The Mathematical Gazette.

[8]  B. O. Koopman On distributions admitting a sufficient statistic , 1936 .

[9]  Amiya K. Basu,et al.  Salesforce Compensation Plans: An Agency Theoretic Perspective , 1985 .

[10]  Gordon Shillinglaw,et al.  Managerial cost accounting , 1982 .

[11]  Bengt Holmstrom,et al.  Moral Hazard and Observability , 1979 .

[12]  Ganapati P. Patil,et al.  Multivariate Exponential-type Distributions , 1968 .

[13]  W. Whitt Uniform conditional stochastic order , 1980 .

[14]  Paul R. Milgrom,et al.  Good News and Bad News: Representation Theorems and Applications , 1981 .

[15]  Gerald A. Feltham Cost Aggregation: An Information Economic Analysis , 1977 .

[16]  Madhav V. Rajan,et al.  Cost Accounting: A Managerial Emphasis , 1972 .

[17]  Robert H. Ashton,et al.  Human Information Processing in Accounting , 1982 .

[18]  William P. Rogerson,et al.  THE FIRST-ORDER APPROACH TO PRINCIPAL-AGENT PROBLEMS , 1985 .

[19]  Frøystein Gjesdal,et al.  Information and Incentives: The Agency Information Problem , 1982 .

[20]  F. Chorlton,et al.  Differential Equations and Applications , 1966 .

[21]  Joel S. Demski,et al.  Economically Optimal Performance Evaluation And Control-Systems , 1980 .

[22]  James B. Scarborough,et al.  Differential Equations and Applications. , 1968 .

[23]  M. Degroot Optimal Statistical Decisions , 1970 .

[24]  P. R. Fisk,et al.  Distributions in Statistics: Continuous Multivariate Distributions , 1971 .

[25]  Rajiv D. Banker,et al.  Unobservable outcomes and multiattribute preferences in the evaluation of managerial performance , 1988 .

[26]  W. R. Buckland,et al.  Distributions in Statistics: Continuous Multivariate Distributions , 1973 .

[27]  Milton C. Chew Distributions in Statistics: Continuous Univariate Distributions-1 and 2 , 1971 .

[28]  Ian N. Sneddon Elements Of Partial Differential Equations , 1957 .

[29]  Gordon Shillinglaw Cost accounting : analysis and control , 1972 .