Human Wagering Behavior Depends on Opponents' Faces

Research in competitive games has exclusively focused on how opponent models are developed through previous outcomes and how peoples' decisions relate to normative predictions. Little is known about how rapid impressions of opponents operate and influence behavior in competitive economic situations, although such subjective impressions have been shown to influence cooperative decision-making. This study investigates whether an opponent's face influences players' wagering decisions in a zero-sum game with hidden information. Participants made risky choices in a simplified poker task while being presented opponents whose faces differentially correlated with subjective impressions of trust. Surprisingly, we find that threatening face information has little influence on wagering behavior, but faces relaying positive emotional characteristics impact peoples' decisions. Thus, people took significantly longer and made more mistakes against emotionally positive opponents. Differences in reaction times and percent correct were greatest around the optimal decision boundary, indicating that face information is predominantly used when making decisions during medium-value gambles. Mistakes against emotionally positive opponents resulted from increased folding rates, suggesting that participants may have believed that these opponents were betting with hands of greater value than other opponents. According to these results, the best “poker face” for bluffing may not be a neutral face, but rather a face that contains emotional correlates of trustworthiness. Moreover, it suggests that rapid impressions of an opponent play an important role in competitive games, especially when people have little or no experience with an opponent.

[1]  Matteo Carandini,et al.  Coding of stimulus sequences by population responses in visual cortex , 2009, Nature Neuroscience.

[2]  Colin Camerer,et al.  Thinking like a trader selectively reduces individuals' loss aversion , 2009, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[3]  Sheng He,et al.  Dynamics of processing invisible faces in the brain: Automatic neural encoding of facial expression information , 2009, NeuroImage.

[4]  Paul R. Schrater,et al.  Structure Learning in Human Sequential Decision-Making , 2008, NIPS.

[5]  A. Todorov,et al.  The functional basis of face evaluation , 2008, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[6]  Alexander Todorov,et al.  Reading trustworthiness in faces without recognizing faces , 2008, Cognitive neuropsychology.

[7]  Pearl H. Chiu,et al.  Self Responses along Cingulate Cortex Reveal Quantitative Neural Phenotype for High-Functioning Autism , 2008, Neuron.

[8]  Andrew D. Engell,et al.  Implicit Trustworthiness Decisions: Automatic Coding of Face Properties in the Human Amygdala , 2007, Journal of Cognitive Neuroscience.

[9]  Erik J Schlicht,et al.  Impact of coordinate transformation uncertainty on human sensorimotor control. , 2007, Journal of neurophysiology.

[10]  R. Dolan,et al.  How the Brain Translates Money into Force: A Neuroimaging Study of Subliminal Motivation , 2007, Science.

[11]  Ahmad R. Hariri,et al.  Facial Expressions of Emotion Reveal Neuroendocrine and Cardiovascular Stress Responses , 2007, Biological Psychiatry.

[12]  A. Yuille,et al.  Opinion TRENDS in Cognitive Sciences Vol.10 No.7 July 2006 Special Issue: Probabilistic models of cognition Vision as Bayesian inference: analysis by synthesis? , 2022 .

[13]  Colin F Camerer,et al.  Agent-Specific Responses in the Cingulate Cortex During Economic Exchanges , 2006, Science.

[14]  M. Delgado,et al.  Perceptions of moral character modulate the neural systems of reward during the trust game , 2005, Nature Neuroscience.

[15]  F. Fang,et al.  Cortical responses to invisible objects in the human dorsal and ventral pathways , 2005, Nature Neuroscience.

[16]  Paul R. Schrater,et al.  Auxiliary object knowledge influences visually-guided interception behavior , 2005, APGV '05.

[17]  S. Quartz,et al.  Getting to Know You: Reputation and Trust in a Two-Person Economic Exchange , 2005, Science.

[18]  S. Shimojo,et al.  Gaze bias both reflects and influences preference , 2003, Nature Neuroscience.

[19]  P. Hancock,et al.  What's a face worth: Noneconomic factors in game playing , 2003, Behavioral and Brain Sciences.

[20]  Colin Camerer Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction , 2003 .

[21]  Laurence T Maloney,et al.  Illuminant estimation as cue combination. , 2002, Journal of vision.

[22]  L. DeBruine Facial resemblance enhances trust , 2002, Proceedings of the Royal Society of London. Series B: Biological Sciences.

[23]  R. Adolphs Neural systems for recognizing emotion , 2002, Current Opinion in Neurobiology.

[24]  J. O'Doherty,et al.  Automatic and intentional brain responses during evaluation of trustworthiness of faces , 2002, Nature Neuroscience.

[25]  Rajesh P. N. Rao,et al.  Probabilistic Models of the Brain: Perception and Neural Function , 2002 .

[26]  M. Ernst,et al.  Humans integrate visual and haptic information in a statistically optimal fashion , 2002, Nature.

[27]  Michael S. Landy,et al.  Bayesian modeling of visual perception , 2002 .

[28]  David J. Fleet,et al.  Probabilistic Models of the Brain : Perception and Neural Function , 2001 .

[29]  Gary E. Bolton,et al.  ERC: A Theory of Equity, Reciprocity, and Competition , 2000 .

[30]  Stephen J. Rassenti,et al.  Reciprocity, Trust, and Payoff Privacy in Extensive Form Bargaining , 1998 .

[31]  D. Levine Modeling Altruism and Spitefulness in Experiments , 1998 .

[32]  Joyce E. Berg,et al.  Trust, Reciprocity, and Social History , 1995 .

[33]  A. Tversky,et al.  Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty , 1992 .

[34]  D. Knill,et al.  Apparent surface curvature affects lightness perception , 1991, Nature.

[35]  Colin Camerer,et al.  EXPERIMENTAL TESTS OF A SEQUENTIAL EQUILIBRIUM REPUTATION MODEL , 1988 .

[36]  S. Sorin,et al.  The LP formulation of finite zero-sum games with incomplete information , 1980 .

[37]  Jean-Pierre Ponssard,et al.  Zero-Sum Games with “Almost” Perfect Information , 1975 .

[38]  R BELLMAN,et al.  Some two person games involving bluffing. , 1949, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America.

[39]  E. Rowland Theory of Games and Economic Behavior , 1946, Nature.

[40]  J. Neumann,et al.  Theory of games and economic behavior , 1945, 100 Years of Math Milestones.