Bidding for a group-specific public-good prize

Abstract We examine the equilibrium effort levels of individual players and groups in a contest in which two groups compete with each other to win a group-specific public-good prize, the players choose their effort levels simultaneously and independently, and the winning group is determined by the selection rule of all-pay auctions. We first prove nonexistence of a pure-strategy Nash equilibrium, and then construct a mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium. At the Nash equilibrium, the only active player in each group is a player whose valuation for the prize is the highest in that group; all the other players expend zero effort; and the equilibrium effort levels depend solely on two values — the highest valuation for the prize in each group.

[1]  Matthew O. Jackson,et al.  Implementing a public project and distributing its cost , 1992 .

[2]  Michael R. Baye,et al.  Rigging the Lobbying Process: An Application of the All-Pay Auction , 1993 .

[3]  Jack Hirshleifer,et al.  From weakest-link to best-shot: Correction , 1985 .

[4]  Jason F. Shogren,et al.  A general model of rent seeking for public goods , 1995 .

[5]  H. Varian Sequential contributions to public goods , 1994 .

[6]  S. Nitzan,et al.  Neutrality and the private provision of public goods with incomplete information , 1994 .

[7]  Wolfgang Leininger,et al.  Asymmetric All-Pay Auctions with Incomplete Information: The Two-Player Case , 1996 .

[8]  H. Ursprung PUBLIC GOODS, RENT DISSIPATION, AND CANDIDATE COMPETITION , 1990 .

[9]  R. Deb,et al.  AUCTION-LIKE MECHANISMS FOR PRICING EXCLUDABLE PUBLIC GOODS , 1999 .

[10]  D. Samet,et al.  Dissipation of contestable rents by small numbers of contenders , 1987 .

[11]  Tatsuyoshi Saijo,et al.  A Voluntary Participation Game with a Non-excludable Public Good , 1999 .

[12]  J. Riley,et al.  The analytics of uncertainty and information: Long-run relationships and the credibility of threats and promises , 1992 .

[13]  Simon Vicary Joint production and the private provision of public goods , 1997 .

[14]  K. Baik Difference-form contest success functions and effort levels in contests , 1998 .

[15]  J. Morgan,et al.  An Analysis of the War of Attrition and the All-Pay Auction , 1997 .

[16]  Ian L. Gale,et al.  Caps on Political Lobbying , 1998 .

[17]  R. Zeckhauser,et al.  An economic theory of alliances , 1966 .

[18]  Tore Ellingsen Strategic Buyers and the Social Cost of Monopoly , 1990 .

[19]  Sidney C. Sufrin,et al.  The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. , 1966 .

[20]  Eyal Winter,et al.  Simple Subscription Mechanisms for Excludable Public Goods , 1999 .

[21]  K. Baik Effort levels in contests: The public-good prize case , 1993 .

[22]  K. Baik RENT‐SEEKING FIRMS, CONSUMER GROUPS, AND THE SOCIAL COSTS OF MONOPOLY , 1999 .

[23]  J. Hirshleifer From weakest-link to best-shot: The voluntary provision of public goods , 1983 .

[24]  J. Riley,et al.  Politically Contestable Rents And Transfers , 1989 .

[25]  M. Hayashi,et al.  Country size and the voluntary provision of international public goods , 1999 .

[26]  Shmuel Nitzan,et al.  Rent-seeking for pure public goods , 1990 .

[27]  M. Olson,et al.  The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. , 1973 .

[28]  Michael R. Baye,et al.  The all-pay auction with complete information , 1990 .

[29]  Ian L. Gale,et al.  Rent dissipation when rent seekers are budget constrained , 1997 .

[30]  P. Kleindorfer,et al.  Auctioning the Provision of an Indivisible Public Good , 1994 .

[31]  H. Varian,et al.  On the private provision of public goods , 1986 .

[32]  T. Groves,et al.  Optimal Allocation of Public Goods: A Solution to the 'Free Rider Problem' , 1977 .

[33]  Derek J. Clark,et al.  Competition over More Than One Prize , 1998 .