Modelling the economic costs of climate policy

The overall objective of this report is to scrutinize previous economic models used to assess the economic costs of climate protection. We pay particular attention to the way in which different model structures and assumptions affect cost estimates, and highlight the limitations and the strengths of different types of models and approaches. The report begins by briefly discussing the concept of economic costs. We present a taxonomy of different costs, and distinguish, in particular, between direct cost, partial equilibrium costs and general equilibrium costs. Non-market costs and the impact of policy design on climate policy costs are also discussed. The different model approaches used to assess the economic impacts of climate policy put particular emphasis on some types of costs while ignoring or simplifying the representation of other costs. The conception of the cost of behavioural change in bottom-up (e.g., systems engineering models) and top-down models (e.g., general equilibrium models, neoclassical growth models etc.) differs; in the former case “a technology” represents a particular activity or process, and the costs of climate policy stems from the extra cost of a discrete shift from an activity/process to another. By contrast, in top-down models no discrete activities are represented, and instead “technology” is defined by continuous production (or cost) functions. The empirical bases for the two model approaches therefore also differ. This also means that in bottom-up models emphasis is placed on a representation of technological detail, while top-down models attempt to provide a theoretically consistent description of overall economy and the interactions be-tween different markets. This suggests that these two model approaches should be considered complements (rather than substitutes), and they have recently been combined in so-called hybrid models. The various model approaches also result in different ways of reporting cost estimates. In the report we discuss the validity of four types of measures: (a) total direct compliance costs; (b) the carbon price required to comply with a given emissions reduction; (c) the loss in gross domestic (or world) product; and (d) the equivalent variation (i.e., the change in income that would lead to the same change in a consumer’s utility as the policy considered). The latter two measures (and in particular the last one) are generally the most appealing ways of reporting costs from an economic-theoretical point of view. The estimated costs of reducing greenhouse gas emissions tend to vary a lot across different models and studies, and in the report we consult previous studies and meta-analyses to systematically review the main assumptions and methodological choices that underlie different cost estimates. We distinguish between four main types of climate policy cost drivers: (a) the baseline scenario; (b) the structural characteristics of the models; (c) the design of climate policy; and (d) the inclusion of non-market costs and benefits. The analysis shows that all these variable categories help explain model outcomes. Many of the variables discussed come out as important also when exposed to quantitative meta-analysis, although in some other cases – e.g., substitution possibilities, level of technological detail etc. – the results are in part unexpected. The importance of policy design – the degree of flexibility permitted in complying with the emission (or stabilization) target – is also well illustrated in previous studies, and poor designs may substantially raise the cost of meeting emissions reduction targets. Over the long-run the development of new technology will be essential in meeting global climate challenges. For this reason the impact of climate policy instruments on technological progress, and ultimately on compliance costs, is of great interest. Such assessments

[1]  A. Huhtala,et al.  Is CO2 Trading Always Beneficial? A CGE-Model Analysis on Secondary Environmental Benefits , 2000 .

[2]  Too Good to Be True? An Examination of Three Economic Assessments of California Climate Change Policy , 2007 .

[3]  L. Goulder,et al.  Environmental taxation and the double dividend: A reader's guide , 1995 .

[4]  Göran Östblom,et al.  Costs of Climate Policy when Pollution Affects Health and Labour Productivity A General Equilibrium Analysis Applied to Sweden , 2004 .

[5]  W. Kip Viscusi,et al.  Energy Taxation as a Policy Instrument to Reduce CO2 Emissions: A Net Benefit Analysis , 1995 .

[6]  Patrik Söderholm,et al.  Wind Power in Europe: A Simultaneous Innovation–Diffusion Model , 2007 .

[7]  Richard S. J. Tol,et al.  The Stern Review of the Economics of Climate Change: A Comment , 2006 .

[8]  Andreas Löschel,et al.  Technological Change in Economic Models of Environmental Policy: A Survey , 2002 .

[9]  Klaus Conrad,et al.  Computable General Equilibrium Models for Environmental Economics and Policy Analysis , 1999 .

[10]  Elhanan Helpman,et al.  International R&D spillovers , 1995 .

[11]  Stephen C. Peck,et al.  CO2 Emissions Control Agreements: Incentives for Regional Participation , 1999 .

[12]  T. Kram,et al.  Endogenous learning and technology clustering: analysis with MARKAL model of the Western European energy system , 2000 .

[13]  Asami Miketa,et al.  The impact of R&D on innovation for wind energy in Denmark, Germany and the United Kingdom , 2005 .

[14]  David Popp,et al.  Entice: Endogenous Technological Change in the Dice Model of Global Warming , 2003 .

[15]  Nebojsa Nakicenovic,et al.  Technological change and the environment , 2002 .

[16]  Winston Harrington,et al.  On the Accuracy of Regulatory Cost Estimates , 2000 .

[17]  K. Nyborg,et al.  The Cold Shiver of Not Giving Enough: On the Social Cost of Recycling Campaigns , 2004, Land Economics.

[18]  A. Jaffe,et al.  The Induced Innovation Hypothesis and Energy-Saving Technological Change , 1998 .

[19]  Jonathan Köhler,et al.  Costs of greenhouse gas abatement: meta-analysis of post-SRES mitigation scenarios , 2002 .

[20]  Mark Lasky,et al.  The Economic Costs of Reducing Emissions of Greenhouse Gases: A Survey of Economic Models , 2003 .

[21]  Leonardo Barreto,et al.  Emission trading and the role of learning-by-doing spillovers in the "bottom-up" energy-system ERIS model , 2004 .

[22]  Socrates Kypreos,et al.  Endogenizing R&D and Market Experience in the "Bottom-Up" Energy-Systems ERIS Model , 2004 .

[23]  Alan S. Manne,et al.  Learn-by-doing and carbon dioxide abatement , 2004 .

[24]  R. Repetto,et al.  The costs of climate protection : a guide for the perplexed , 1997 .

[25]  J. Bollen,et al.  UvA-DARE ( Digital Academic Repository ) A trade view on climate change policies : a multi-region multi-sector approach , 2009 .

[26]  Andrii Gritsevskyi,et al.  Modeling uncertainty of induced technological change , 2000 .

[27]  C. Kolstad,et al.  The Economics of Climate Policy , 2005 .

[28]  R. Lucas On the Mechanics of Economic Development , 1988 .

[29]  William D. Nordhaus,et al.  A Regional Dynamic General-Equilibrium Model of Alternative Climate-Change Strategies , 1996 .

[30]  Alan S. Manne,et al.  The Kyoto Protocol: A Cost-Effective Strategy for Meeting Environmental Objectives? , 1999 .

[31]  M. Hill,et al.  Sectoral EU-trading and other Climate Policy Options: Impacts on the Swedish Economy , 2002 .

[32]  P. Ekins Rethinking the costs related to global warming: A survey of the issues , 1995, Environmental and Resource Economics.

[33]  Richard G. Richels,et al.  The costs of CO2 emission reductions: Some insights from global analyses , 1996 .

[34]  John Hicks,et al.  The Theory of Wages , 1933 .

[35]  C. Nilsson Studies in environmental economics : numerical analysis of greenhouse gas policies , 2004 .

[36]  Thomas Sundqvist,et al.  Using the market at a cost: How the introduction of green certificates in Sweden led to market inefficiencies , 2007 .

[37]  W. Arthur,et al.  Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy , 1996 .

[38]  R. Tol Modelling the costs of emission reduction: different approaches , 2000 .

[39]  Tomas Ekvall,et al.  Benefits from increased cooperation and energy trade under CO2 commitments - The Nordic case , 2003 .

[40]  W. Nordhaus The "Stern Review" on the Economics of Climate Change , 2006 .

[41]  Leo Schrattenholzer,et al.  Learning rates for energy technologies , 2001 .

[42]  A. Jaffe,et al.  A tale of two market failures: Technology and environmental policy , 2005 .

[43]  Elhanan Helpman,et al.  Endogenous Innovation in the Theory of Growth , 1993 .

[44]  Socrates Kypreos,et al.  A post-Kyoto analysis with the ERIS model prototype , 2000 .

[45]  I. Wing,et al.  Adjustment Time, Capital Malleability and Policy Cost , 1999 .

[46]  Thomas F. Rutherford,et al.  Effects of Restrictions on International Permit Trading: The MS-MRT Model , 1999 .

[47]  Kristina Söderholm Environmental awakening in the Swedish pulp and paper industry: pollution resistance and firm responses in the Early 20th century , 2009 .

[48]  Patrik Söderholm,et al.  Modeling technical change in energy system analysis: analyzing the introduction of learning-by-doing in bottom-up energy models , 2006 .

[49]  A. Bovenberg,et al.  Optimal taxation, public goods and environmental policy with involuntary unemployment , 1996 .

[50]  J. Edmonds,et al.  A review of mitigation cost studies , 1996 .

[51]  D. Nestor,et al.  Alternative specifications for environmental control costs in a general equilibrium framework , 1995 .

[52]  L. Argote,et al.  Learning Curves in Manufacturing , 1990, Science.

[53]  R. Mooij,et al.  Environmental Levies and Distortionary Taxation. , 1994 .

[54]  Hadi Dowlatabadi,et al.  Sensitivity of climate change mitigation estimates to assumptions about technical change , 1998 .

[55]  Nick Mabey,et al.  Are environmental taxes a free lunch? Issues in modelling the macroeconomic effects of carbon taxes , 1997 .

[56]  Göran Östblom An Environmental Medium Term Economic Model - EMEC , 1999 .

[57]  W. Cline Economics of Global Warming, The , 1992 .

[58]  William D. Nordhaus,et al.  Modeling Induced Innovation in Climate Change Policy , 2002 .

[59]  John P. Robinson,et al.  Mitigating factors : Assessing the costs of reducing GHG emissions , 1996 .

[60]  Stephen P. A. Brown,et al.  The Kyoto Protocol: An Economic Analysis Using GTEM , 1999 .

[61]  I. Wing,et al.  Joint Program on the Science and Policy of Global Change Induced Technical Change and the Cost of Climate Policy , 2022 .

[62]  Marzio Galeotti,et al.  Endogenous Induced Technical Change and the Costs of Kyoto , 2001 .

[63]  Dallas Burtraw,et al.  Revenue-Raising versus Other Approaches to Environmental Protection: The Critical Significance of Preexisting Tax Distortions , 1997 .

[64]  A. Ellerman,et al.  The Declining Trend in Sulfur Dioxide Emissions: Implications for Allowance Prices☆ , 1998 .

[65]  Clas-Otto Wene,et al.  ASSESSING NEW ENERGY TECHNOLOGIES USING AN ENERGY SYSTEM MODEL WITH ENDOGENIZED EXPERIENCE CURVES , 1997 .

[66]  Knut Einar Rosendahl,et al.  Cost-effective environmental policy: Implications of induced technological change , 2004 .

[67]  B. Zwaan,et al.  Long-term substitutability between environmental and man-made goods , 2002 .

[68]  R. Schmalensee The costs of environmental protection , 1993 .

[69]  QK Ahmad,et al.  Climate change 1995. Economic and social dimensions of climate change. Contribution of working group III to the second assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change , 1997 .

[70]  M. Porter,et al.  Toward a New Conception of the Environment-Competitiveness Relationship , 1995 .

[71]  Haoran Pan,et al.  The cost efficiency of Kyoto flexible mechanisms: a top-down study with the GEM-E3 world model , 2005, Environ. Model. Softw..

[72]  Sidney C. Sufrin,et al.  The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. , 1966 .

[73]  D. Jorgenson,et al.  Reducing US carbon emissions: an econometric general equilibrium assessment , 1993 .

[74]  J. Sijm INDUCED TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE AND SPILLOVERS IN CLIMATE POLICY MODELING , 2004 .

[75]  Arnulf Grubler,et al.  Technological change and the timing of mitigation measures , 1998 .

[76]  Niclas Mattsson,et al.  Internalizing technological development in energy systems models , 1997 .

[77]  Thomas Unger,et al.  Common Energy and Climate Strategies for the Nordic Countries - A Model Analysis , 2003 .

[78]  Wallace E. Oates,et al.  Tightening Environmental Standards: The Benefit-Cost or the No-Cost Paradigm? , 1995 .

[79]  Patrik Söderholm,et al.  Kostnadseffektiva styrmedel i den svenska klimat- och energipolitiken? : metodologiska frågeställningar och empiriska tillämpningar , 2005 .

[80]  K. Arrow The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing , 1962 .

[81]  Anil Markandya,et al.  Does the Kyoto Protocol Cost Too Much and Create Unbreakable Barriers for Economic Growth? , 2006 .

[82]  Lena Neij,et al.  Experience curves for wind power , 2004 .

[83]  William D. Nordhaus,et al.  The Allocation of Energy Resources , 1973 .

[84]  Stephen H. Schneider,et al.  Induced technological change and the attractiveness of CO2 abatement policies , 1999 .

[85]  Knut Einar Rosendahl,et al.  Co2 Mitigation Costs and Ancillary Benefits in the Nordic Countries, the UK and Ireland: A Survey , 2001 .

[86]  Michael Grubb,et al.  Induced Technological Change: Exploring its Implications for the Economics of Atmospheric Stabilization: Synthesis Report from the innovation Modeling Comparison Project , 2006 .

[87]  S. Messner,et al.  Endogenized technological learning in an energy systems model , 1997 .

[88]  John P. Weyant,et al.  Costs of Reducing Global Carbon Emissions , 1993 .

[89]  Ian Sue Wing,et al.  Representing induced technological change in models for climate policy analysis , 2006 .

[90]  P. Romer Endogenous Technological Change , 1989, Journal of Political Economy.

[91]  L. Bergman General equilibrium effects of environmental policy: A CGE-modeling approach , 1991, Environmental and Resource Economics.

[92]  M. Olson,et al.  The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups , 1969 .

[93]  J. Edmonds,et al.  Economic and environmental choices in the stabilization of atmospheric CO2 concentrations , 1996, Nature.

[94]  G. Nicoletti,et al.  GREEN a Multi-Sector, Multi-Region General Equilibrium Model for Quantifying the Costs of Curbing CO2 Emissions: A Technical Manual , 1992 .

[95]  C. Nilsson,et al.  A Unilateral Versus a Multilateral Carbon Dioxide Tax - A Numerical Analysis with the European Model GEM-E3 , 1999 .

[96]  Joel Darmstadter,et al.  Winner, Loser, or Innocent Victim? Has Renewable Energy Performed As Expected? , 2000 .

[97]  Bob van der Zwaan,et al.  Gross world product and consumption in a global warming model with endogenous technological change , 2003 .

[98]  Richard G. Richels,et al.  The Attached Material Is Posted on Regulation2point0.org with Permission. the Impact of Learning-by-doing on the Timing and Costs of Co 2 Abatement the Impact of Learning-by-doing on the Timing and Costs of Co 2 Abatement , 2022 .

[99]  S. Isoard,et al.  Endogenous learning in world post-Kyoto scenarios: application of the POLES model under adaptive expectations , 2000 .

[100]  Richard D. Morgenstern,et al.  Carbon Abatement Costs: Why the Wide Range of Estimates? , 2006 .

[101]  Tom Nicholas,et al.  Was Electricity a General Purpose Technology? Evidence from Historical Patent Citations , 2004 .

[102]  Göran Östblom,et al.  The EMEC model: Version 2.0 , 2006 .

[103]  Alex Cristofaro,et al.  Optimizing Tax Strategies to Reduce Greenhouse Gases Without Curtailing Growth , 1991 .

[104]  Adrian Cooper,et al.  The Economic Implications of Reducing Carbon Emissions , 1999 .

[105]  David Popp,et al.  Induced Innovation and Energy Prices , 2001 .

[106]  W. Pizer,et al.  Calculating the Costs of Environmental Regulation , 2005 .

[107]  L. Goulder,et al.  Optimal Co2 Abatement in the Presence of Induced Technological Change , 1998 .

[108]  Kristian Lindgren,et al.  Induced Technological Change in a Limited Foresight Optimization Model , 2005 .

[109]  John P. Weyant,et al.  Overview of EMF-21: Multigas Mitigation and Climate Policy , 2006 .

[110]  R. Dellink Modelling the Costs of Environmental Policy: a Dynamic Applied General Equilibrium Assessment , 2005 .

[111]  Charlotte Nilsson,et al.  The Costs of Going from Kyoto to Marrakech: Swedish Carbon Policy in a Multi-Regional Model , 2002 .

[112]  William D. Nordhaus,et al.  Managing The Global Commons , 1994 .

[113]  Jonathan Köhler,et al.  Decarbonizing the Global Economy with Induced Technological Change: Scenarios to 2100 using E3MG , 2006 .

[114]  Richard S. Eckaus,et al.  The MIT Emissions Prediction and Policy Analysis (EPPA) model : revisions, sensitivities, and comparisons of results , 2001 .

[115]  B. Carlén EU's Emissions Trading System in the Presence of National Emission Targets , 2004 .

[116]  Antonio Soria,et al.  Modelling energy technology dynamics: methodology for adaptive expectations models with learning by doing and learning by searching , 2000 .

[117]  Steven G. Medema,et al.  The marginal efficiency effects of taxes and subsidies in the presence of externalities: A computational general equilibrium approach , 1993 .

[118]  Michael Grubb,et al.  The Costs of Limiting Fossil-Fuel CO2 Emissions: A Survey and Analysis , 1993 .

[119]  P Ekins,et al.  The Costs of Kyoto for the US Economy , 2004 .

[120]  John M. Reilly,et al.  The costs of the Kyoto protocol in the European Union , 2003 .