The Formation of Social Conventions in Real-Time Environments

Why are some behaviors governed by strong social conventions while others are not? We experimentally investigate two factors contributing to the formation of conventions in a game of impure coordination: the continuity of interaction within each round of play (simultaneous vs. real-time) and the stakes of the interaction (high vs. low differences between payoffs). To maximize efficiency and fairness in this game, players must coordinate on one of two equally advantageous equilibria. In agreement with other studies manipulating continuity of interaction, we find that players who were allowed to interact continuously within rounds achieved outcomes with greater efficiency and fairness than players who were forced to make simultaneous decisions. However, the stability of equilibria in the real-time condition varied systematically and dramatically with stakes: players converged on more stable patterns of behavior when stakes are high. To account for this result, we present a novel analysis of the dynamics of continuous interaction and signaling within rounds. We discuss this previously unconsidered interaction between within-trial and across-trial dynamics as a form of social canalization. When stakes are low in a real-time environment, players can satisfactorily coordinate ‘on the fly’, but when stakes are high there is increased pressure to establish and adhere to shared expectations that persist across rounds.

[1]  David M. Kreps,et al.  Game Theory and Economic Modelling , 1992 .

[2]  Daniel Friedman,et al.  Separating the Hawks from the Doves: Evidence from Continuous Time Laboratory Games , 2010, J. Econ. Theory.

[3]  Lubos Buzna,et al.  Self-Organized Pedestrian Crowd Dynamics: Experiments, Simulations, and Design Solutions , 2005, Transp. Sci..

[4]  S. Garrod,et al.  Conversation, co-ordination and convention: an empirical investigation of how groups establish linguistic conventions , 1994, Cognition.

[5]  R. Aumann Subjectivity and Correlation in Randomized Strategies , 1974 .

[6]  Philip R. Cohen,et al.  Referring as a Collaborative Process , 2003 .

[7]  D. Helbing,et al.  Homo Socialis: An Analytical Core for Sociological Theory , 2013 .

[8]  Daniel Friedman,et al.  Continuous time and communication in a public-goods experiment , 2014 .

[9]  Geoffrey E. Hinton,et al.  How Learning Can Guide Evolution , 1996, Complex Syst..

[10]  Marisa Casillas Learning to take turns , 2014, ICCA 2014.

[11]  Paul Ormerod A Comment on Gintis and Helbing “Homo Socialis: An Analytical Core for Sociological Theory†, 2015 .

[12]  S. Garrod,et al.  Saying what you mean in dialogue: A study in conceptual and semantic co-ordination , 1987, Cognition.

[13]  C. Bicchieri The grammar of society: the nature and dynamics of social norms , 2005 .

[14]  H. H. Clark,et al.  Conceptual pacts and lexical choice in conversation. , 1996, Journal of experimental psychology. Learning, memory, and cognition.

[15]  Robert L. Goldstone,et al.  Cyclic Game Dynamics Driven by Iterated Reasoning , 2013, PloS one.

[16]  Barry Sopher,et al.  Social Learning and Coordination Conventions in Intergenerational Games: An Experimental Study , 2003, Journal of Political Economy.

[17]  C. Waddington,et al.  GENETIC ASSIMILATION OF THE BITHORAX PHENOTYPE , 1956 .

[18]  R. Kirk CONVENTION: A PHILOSOPHICAL STUDY , 1970 .

[19]  Michael J. Spivey,et al.  Continuous Dynamics in Real-Time Cognition , 2006 .

[20]  Siobhan Chapman Logic and Conversation , 2005 .

[21]  Daniël Wedema Games And Information An Introduction To Game Theory 3rd Edition , 2011 .

[22]  Robert X D Hawkins,et al.  Conducting real-time multiplayer experiments on the web , 2014, Behavior Research Methods.

[23]  Matthew O. Jackson,et al.  Culture-dependent strategies in coordination games , 2014, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[24]  C. Waddington Canalization of Development and the Inheritance of Acquired Characters , 1942, Nature.

[25]  Andrea Baronchelli,et al.  The spontaneous emergence of conventions: An experimental study of cultural evolution , 2015, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences.

[26]  Kenny Smith,et al.  Cultural Evolution and Perpetuation of Arbitrary Communicative Conventions in Experimental Microsocieties , 2012, PloS one.

[27]  Dirk Helbing,et al.  How Individuals Learn to Take Turns: Emergence of Alternating Cooperation in a Congestion Game and the Prisoner's Dilemma , 2005, Adv. Complex Syst..

[28]  Vai-Lam Mui,et al.  Using Turn Taking to Mitigate Coordination and Conflict Problems in the Repeated Battle of the Sexes Game , 2008 .

[29]  R. Beer Dynamical approaches to cognitive science , 2000, Trends in Cognitive Sciences.

[30]  David Lewis Convention: A Philosophical Study , 1986 .

[31]  K. Taylor Natural justice. , 1998, The Lamp.

[32]  E. Rowland Theory of Games and Economic Behavior , 1946, Nature.

[33]  Sang Joon Kim,et al.  A Mathematical Theory of Communication , 2006 .

[34]  Joseph G. Johnson,et al.  Response dynamics: A new window on the decision process , 2011, Judgment and Decision Making.

[35]  G. S. van Doorn,et al.  Coaction versus reciprocity in continuous-time models of cooperation. , 2014, Journal of theoretical biology.

[36]  D. Friedman,et al.  A Continuous Dilemma ∠, 2009 .

[37]  Roberto A. Weber,et al.  Cultural Conflict and Merger Failure: An Experimental Approach , 2003, Manag. Sci..