Axiomatic characterizations under players nullification

Many axiomatic characterizations of values for cooperative games invoke axioms which evaluate the consequences of removing an arbitrary player. Balanced contributions (Myerson, 1980) and balanced cycle contributions (Kamijo and Kongo, 2010) are two well-known examples of such axioms. We revisit these characterizations by nullifying a player instead of deleting her/him from a game. The nullification (Beal et al., 2014a) of a player is obtained by transforming a game into a new one in which this player is a null player, i.e. the worth of the coalitions containing this player is now identical to that of the same coalition without this player. The degree with which our results are close to the original results in the literature is connected to the fact that the targeted value satisfies the null player out axiom (Derks and Haller, 1999).

[1]  Takumi Kongo,et al.  Whose deletion does not affect your payoff? The difference between the Shapley value, the egalitarian value, the solidarity value, and the Banzhaf value , 2012, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[2]  L. Shapley A Value for n-person Games , 1988 .

[3]  André Casajus Collusion, quarrel, and the Banzhaf value , 2014, Int. J. Game Theory.

[4]  P. Solal,et al.  Balanced collective contributions, the equal allocation of non-separable costs and application to data sharing games , 2014 .

[5]  Juan J. Vidal-Puga,et al.  The axiomatic approach to three values in games with coalition structure , 2010, Eur. J. Oper. Res..

[6]  William Thomson,et al.  ON THE AXIOMATICS OF RESOURCE ALLOCATION: INTERPRETING THE CONSISTENCY PRINCIPLE , 2012, Economics and Philosophy.

[7]  S. Hart,et al.  Potential, value, and consistency , 1989 .

[8]  Hans Haller,et al.  Null Players Out? Linear Values for Games with Variable Supports , 1999, IGTR.

[9]  Roger B. Myerson,et al.  Graphs and Cooperation in Games , 1977, Math. Oper. Res..

[10]  Sylvain Béal,et al.  Characterizations of weighted and equal division values , 2016 .

[11]  G. Owen,et al.  The consistent Shapley value for hyperplane games , 1989 .

[12]  E. Kalai,et al.  On weighted Shapley values , 1983 .

[13]  P. Jean-Jacques Herings,et al.  The average tree solution for cycle-free graph games , 2008, Games Econ. Behav..

[14]  R. Myerson Conference structures and fair allocation rules , 1978 .

[15]  Pierre Dehez,et al.  HOW TO SHARE JOINT LIABILITY: A COOPERATIVE GAME APPROACH , 2012 .

[16]  Takumi Kongo,et al.  Axiomatization of the Shapley value using the balanced cycle contributions property , 2010, Int. J. Game Theory.

[17]  Moni Naor,et al.  On fairness in the carpool problem , 2005, J. Algorithms.

[18]  Ron Holzman,et al.  The core and the bargaining set in glove-market games , 2003, Int. J. Game Theory.

[19]  H. Moulin Equal or proportional division of a surplus, and other methods , 1987 .

[20]  Solidarity within a fixed community , 2014 .

[21]  Hans Haller,et al.  Collusion properties of values , 1994 .

[22]  J. M. Bilbao,et al.  Contributions to the Theory of Games , 2005 .

[23]  Vito Fragnelli,et al.  Tree-connected peer group situations and peer group games , 2002, Math. Methods Oper. Res..

[24]  François Maniquet,et al.  A characterization of the Shapley value in queueing problems , 2003, J. Econ. Theory.

[25]  Eitan Zemel,et al.  Totally Balanced Games and Games of Flow , 1982, Math. Oper. Res..

[26]  Marc Fleurbaey,et al.  Compensation and responsibility , 2011 .