Induced Technical Change: Evidence and Implications for Energy-Environmental Modelling and Policy

Technical change is important in addressing environmental issues, and becomes particularly so concerning difficult, long-term and global issues like climate change. This conclusion is confirmed by data on specific technologies identified, and by and almost all economic modeling sensitivity studies. However, the discussion often obscures a key distinction between: • autonomous technical change, which depends mostly on autonomous trends and government R&D; and • induced technical change, which depends mostly upon corporate investment (R&D, and learning-by-doing) in response to market conditions. There is very strong evidence that much technical change in the energy sector is of the second kind. Evidence comes from studies of specific technology costs as a function of market conditions and investment; the generation and persistence of energy efficiency potentials including international comparisons; and energy demand trends through the price shocks. Action to limit emissions or otherwise create markets for cleaner technologies can therefore be expected to result in technological improvements including cost reductions. Incorporating such induced technical change (ITC) in economic models (making it endogenous to the models) is very complex. It makes the modeling inherently non-linear and complex, with path dependencies and the potential for multiple equilibria. Such treatment is beyond the scope of the major E3 models currently in use. In these models, technical change is incorporated through exogenous assumptions and this is potentially an important weakness. Specific models devoted to investigating ITC have emerged during the mid and late 1990s. These models show that it can alter results in many ways. Models that draw upon the empirical engineering literature tend to show very large impacts indeed. Models in which innovation is a constrained resource that may be shifted from one sector to another tend to show lesser effects. Other and simpler approaches also show results that appear quantitatively quite divergent. These differences require further exploration but do not undermine the conclusion that induced technical change is likely to be important in the context of long-term issues like climate change. New efforts are seeking to incorporate ITC in more mainstream E3 models but results are not yet available that enable the impact of ITC to be estimated in these models. Overall the economic and policy implications of ITC appear to be as follows; the findings are summarised in Table E1 (drawn from the concluding section): Long run costs. Several (but not all) studies incorporating ITC suggest that it could make addressing climate change – …

[1]  Michael Grubb,et al.  The economics of changing course : Implications of adaptability and inertia for optimal climate policy , 1995 .

[2]  Environmental Programme,et al.  Emerging Energy Technologies: Impacts and Policy Implications , 1992 .

[3]  C. Fischer,et al.  How Important is Technological Innovation in Protecting the Environment? , 2000 .

[4]  Nebojsa Nakicenovic,et al.  Dynamics of energy technologies and global change , 1999 .

[5]  Tom Kram,et al.  A multinational model for CO2 reduction: Defining boundaries of future CO2 emissions in nine countries , 1996 .

[6]  Franz Wirl,et al.  Irreversible Price-Induced Efficiency Improvements: Theory and Empirical Application to Road Transportation , 1993 .

[7]  Arnulf Grubler,et al.  Technological change and the timing of mitigation measures , 1998 .

[8]  William D. Nordhaus,et al.  Modeling Induced Innovation in Climate Change Policy , 2002 .

[9]  Dennis Anderson Technical progress and pollution abatement: an economic view of selected technologies and practices , 2001, Environment and Development Economics.

[10]  J. Dargay Are Price and Income Elasticities of Demand Constant , 1992 .

[11]  William A. Pizer,et al.  The optimal choice of climate change policy in the presence of uncertainty , 1999 .

[12]  Henry D. Jacoby,et al.  Integrated Global System Model for Climate Policy Assessment: Feedbacks and Sensitivity Studies , 1999 .

[13]  Jean Charles Hourcade,et al.  Modelling long-run scenarios , 1993 .

[14]  Y. Smeers,et al.  Double Dividend Analysis: First Results of a General Equilibrium Model (GEM-E3) linking the EU-12 Countries , 1996 .

[15]  M. Grubb Economic dimensions of technological and global responses to the Kyoto protocol , 2000 .

[16]  L. Goulder,et al.  Optimal Co2 Abatement in the Presence of Induced Technological Change , 1998 .

[17]  Hadi Dowlatabadi,et al.  Sensitivity of climate change mitigation estimates to assumptions about technical change , 1998 .

[18]  Jonathan Köhler,et al.  Equity and ecotax reform in the EU: achieving a 10 per cent reduction in CO2 emissions using excise duties , 1998 .

[19]  Dennis Anderson,et al.  Dynamic simulation and environmental policy analysis: beyond comparative statics and the environmental Kuznets curve , 2001 .

[20]  Thomas E. Drennen,et al.  Renewable Energy: Sources for Fuels and Electricity , 1994 .

[21]  Dermot Gately,et al.  The Imperfect Price-Reversibility of World Oil Demand , 1993 .

[22]  Martin L. Weitzman,et al.  Sustainability and Technical Progress , 1997 .

[23]  R. Tol Spatial and Temporal Efficiency in Climate Policy: Applications of FUND , 1999 .

[24]  W. Brown Argument in the Greenhouse: The International Economics of Controlling Global Warming , 1998 .

[25]  R. Leemans,et al.  Global change scenarios of the 21st Century : results from the IMAGE 2.1 model , 1998 .

[26]  Benno Büeler,et al.  Solving an equilibrium model for trade of CO2 emission permits , 1997 .

[27]  J. Bruce,et al.  Climate change, 1995 : economic and social dimensions of climate change , 1997 .

[28]  Serie research memoranda An Empirical Model for Endogenous Technology in the Netherlands , 1992 .

[29]  Erica L. Plambeck,et al.  The model: Integrating the science and economics of global warming , 1997 .

[30]  N. Nakicenovic,et al.  Costs, Impacts, and Benefits of CO2 Mitigation , 1993 .

[31]  W. Nordhaus Managing the Global Commons: The Economics of Climate Change , 1994 .

[32]  Marzio Galeotti,et al.  Economic growth, international competitiveness and environmental protection: R & D and innovation strategies with the WARM model , 1997 .

[33]  Linear versus nonlinear technical progress: theory and some evidence , 1999 .

[34]  G. Nicoletti,et al.  GREEN - - A Multi-Region Dynamic General Equilibrium Model for Quantifying the Costs of Curbing CO2 Emissions , 1991 .

[35]  Stelios Kafandaris,et al.  Buying Greenhouse Insurance: The Economic Costs of CO2 Emission Limits , 1992 .

[36]  W. Arthur,et al.  Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy , 1996 .

[37]  R. Kemp Environmental policy and technical change , 1997 .

[38]  Nagesh Kumar,et al.  Globalization, Foreign Direct Investment and Technology Transfers : Impacts on and Prospects for Developing Countries , 1998 .

[39]  R. Mooij,et al.  Endogenizing technological progress: The MESEMET Model , 1997 .

[40]  R. Repetto,et al.  The costs of climate protection : a guide for the perplexed , 1997 .

[41]  J. Hourcade,et al.  Climate modelling and policy strategies. The role of technical change and uncertainty , 1998 .

[42]  Andrii Gritsevskyi,et al.  Modeling uncertainty of induced technological change , 2000 .

[43]  Dennis Anderson,et al.  Uncertainties in Responding to Climate Change: On the Economic Value of Technology Policies for Reducing Costs and Creating Options , 2001 .

[44]  Andreas Löschel,et al.  Technological Change in Economic Models of Environmental Policy: A Survey , 2002 .

[45]  Dj Gielen Toward integrated energy and materials policies?: A case study on CO2 reduction in the Netherlands , 1995 .