Empirical Evaluation of Voting Rules with Strictly Ordered Preference Data

The study of voting systems often takes place in the theoretical domain due to a lack of large samples of sincere, strictly ordered voting data.We derive several million elections (more than all the existing studies combined) from a publicly available data, the Netflix Prize dataset. The Netflix data is derived from millions of Netflix users, who have an incentive to report sincere preferences, unlike random survey takers. We evaluate each of these elections under the Plurality, Borda, k-Approval, and Repeated Alternative Vote (RAV) voting rules.We examine the Condorcet Efficiency of each of the rules and the probability of occurrence of Condorcet's Paradox. We compare our votes to existing theories of domain restriction (e.g., single-peakedness) and statistical models used to generate election data for testing (e.g., Impartial Culture). We find a high consensus among the different voting rules; almost no instances of Condorcet's Paradox; almost no support for restricted preference profiles, and very little support for many of the statistical models currently used to generate election data for testing.

[1]  D. Black On the Rationale of Group Decision-making , 1948, Journal of Political Economy.

[2]  L. A. Goodman,et al.  Social Choice and Individual Values , 1951 .

[3]  Amartya Sen,et al.  A Possibility Theorem on Majority Decisions , 1966 .

[4]  R. Niemi The occurrence of the paradox of voting in University elections , 1970 .

[5]  H. Nurmi Voting Procedures: A Summary Analysis , 1983, British Journal of Political Science.

[6]  Clyde H. Coombs,et al.  Social Choice Observed: Five Presidential Elections of the American Psychological Association , 1984, The Journal of Politics.

[7]  S. Merrill A Comparison of Efficiency of Multicandidate Electoral Systems , 1984 .

[8]  S. Berg Paradox of voting under an urn model: The effect of homogeneity , 1985 .

[9]  A. Rapoport,et al.  An Empirical Evaluation of Six Voting Procedures: Do They Really Make Any Difference? , 1993, British Journal of Political Science.

[10]  Karl Rihaczek,et al.  1. WHAT IS DATA MINING? , 2019, Data Mining for the Social Sciences.

[11]  Ian Witten,et al.  Data Mining , 2000 .

[12]  W. Gehrlein Condorcet's paradox and the likelihood of its occurrence: different perspectives on balanced preferences* , 2002 .

[13]  Hitoshi Matsushima,et al.  Handbook of Social Choice and Welfare, Volume 1 (Book) , 2004 .

[14]  Vincent Conitzer,et al.  Common Voting Rules as Maximum Likelihood Estimators , 2005, UAI.

[15]  A. A. J. Marley,et al.  Behavioral Social Choice - Probabilistic Models, Statistical Inference, and Applications , 2006 .

[16]  Michel Regenwetter,et al.  The Unexpected Empirical Consensus Among Consensus Methods , 2007, Psychological science.

[17]  James Bennett,et al.  The Netflix Prize , 2007 .

[18]  Martin Grohe The complexity of homomorphism and constraint satisfaction problems seen from the other side , 2007, JACM.

[19]  Vincent Conitzer,et al.  When are elections with few candidates hard to manipulate? , 2007, J. ACM.

[20]  Edith Hemaspaandra,et al.  Bypassing Combinatorial Protections: Polynomial-Time Algorithms for Single-Peaked Electorates , 2010, AAAI.

[21]  Tim Roughgarden,et al.  Algorithmic Game Theory , 2007 .

[22]  R. Rivest,et al.  An Optimal Single-Winner Preferential Voting System Based on Game Theory , 2010 .

[23]  Toby Walsh,et al.  An Empirical Study of the Manipulability of Single Transferable Voting , 2010, ECAI.

[24]  K. Arrow,et al.  Handbook of Social Choice and Welfare , 2011 .

[25]  Toby Walsh,et al.  Where are the hard manipulation problems? , 2010, J. Artif. Intell. Res..

[26]  Florenz Plassmann,et al.  Modeling the Outcomes of Vote-Casting in Actual Elections , 2011 .

[27]  Piotr Faliszewski,et al.  A Richer Understanding of the Complexity of Election Systems , 2006, Fundamental Problems in Computing.