This article analyzes the feasibility of attaining a variety of climate targets during the 21st century, under alternative cooperation regimes by groups of countries. Five climate targets of increasing severity are analyzed, following the EMF-22 experiment. Each target is attempted under two cooperation regimes, a First Best scenario where all countries fully cooperate from 2012 on, and a Second Best scenario where the World is partitioned into three groups, and each group of countries enters the cooperation at a different date, and implement emission abatement actions in a progressive manner, once in the coalition. The resulting ten combinations are simulated via the ETSAP-TIAM technology based, integrated assessment model. In addition to the 10 separate case analyses, the article proposes a probabilistic treatment of three targets under the First Best scenario, and shows that the three forcing targets may in fact be interpreted as a single target on global temperature change, while assuming that the climate sensitivity Cs is uncertain. It is shown that such an interpretation is possible only if the probability distribution of Cs is carefully chosen.
The analysis of the results shows that the lowest forcing level is unattainable unless immediate coordinated action is undertaken by all countries, and even so only at a high global cost. The middle and the high forcing levels are feasible at affordable global costs, even under the Second Best scenario. Another original contribution of this article is to explain why certain combinations of technological choices are made by the model, and in particular why the climate target clearly supersedes the usually accepted objective of improving energy efficiency. The analysis shows that under some climate targets, it is not optimal to improve energy efficiency, but rather to take advantage of certain technologies that help to reach the climate objective, but that happen to be less energy efficient than even the technologies in the reference scenario. This is particularly observable in the power generation sector and in some end-use sectors. Finally, the article discusses the pros and cons of the stochastic programming treatment of forcing targets, and compares it with the separate simulations of the various deterministic cases.
[1]
M. Salvia,et al.
Integration Of Country Energy System ModelsIn A Pan European FrameworkFor Supporting EU Policies
,
2006
.
[2]
Maryse Labriet,et al.
Modeling Uncertainty in a Large Scale Integrated Energy-Climate Model
,
2009
.
[3]
Gary Yohe,et al.
To Hedge or Not Against an Uncertain Climate Future?
,
2004,
Science.
[4]
R. Wets,et al.
Stochastic programming
,
1989
.
[5]
Michael E. Schlesinger,et al.
Objective estimation of the probability density function for climate sensitivity
,
2001
.
[6]
Guillermo Rein,et al.
Smouldering natural fires: comparison of burning dynamics in boreal peat and Mediterranean humus.
,
2008
.
[7]
Sergey Paltsev,et al.
The Influence on Climate Change of Differing Scenarios for Future Development Analyzed Using the MIT Integrated Global System Model
,
2008
.
[8]
Maryse Labriet,et al.
ETSAP-TIAM: the TIMES integrated assessment model Part I: Model structure
,
2008,
Comput. Manag. Sci..
[9]
M. Weitzman,et al.
On Modeling and Interpreting the Economics of Catastrophic Climate Change
,
2009,
The Review of Economics and Statistics.
[10]
Richard Loulou,et al.
ETSAP-TIAM: the TIMES integrated assessment model. part II: mathematical formulation
,
2008,
Comput. Manag. Sci..
[11]
R. Loulou,et al.
The role of nuclear energy in long-term climate scenarios: An analysis with the World-TIMES model
,
2007
.
[12]
Corinne Le Quéré,et al.
Climate Change 2013: The Physical Science Basis
,
2013
.
[13]
Amit Kanudia,et al.
USING ADVANCED TECHNOLOGY-RICH MODELS FOR REGIONAL AND GLOBAL ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF GHG MITIGATION
,
2002
.
[14]
W. Nordhaus,et al.
Roll the DICE Again: Economic Models of Global Warming
,
1999
.