On the likelihood of single-peaked preferences

This paper contains an extensive combinatorial analysis of the single-peaked domain restriction and investigates the likelihood that an election is single-peaked. We provide a very general upper bound result for domain restrictions that can be defined by certain forbidden configurations. This upper bound implies that many domain restrictions (including the single-peaked restriction) are very unlikely to appear in a random election chosen according to the Impartial Culture assumption. For single-peaked elections, this upper bound can be refined and complemented by a lower bound that is asymptotically tight. In addition, we provide exact results for elections with few voters or candidates. Moreover, we consider the Pólya urn model and the Mallows model and obtain lower bounds showing that single-peakedness is considerably more likely to appear for certain parameterizations.

[1]  A. Slinko,et al.  Exploratory Analysis of Similarities Between Social Choice Rules , 2006 .

[2]  William V. Gehrlein,et al.  The impact of voters' preference diversity on the probability of some electoral outcomes , 2013, Math. Soc. Sci..

[3]  Olivier Spanjaard,et al.  Kemeny Elections with Bounded Single-Peaked or Single-Crossing Width , 2013, IJCAI.

[4]  Gábor Erdélyi,et al.  Computational Aspects of Nearly Single-Peaked Electorates , 2012, AAAI.

[5]  Faruk Gul,et al.  Generalized Median Voter Schemes and Committees , 1993 .

[6]  Craig Boutilier,et al.  Efficient Vote Elicitation under Candidate Uncertainty , 2013, IJCAI.

[7]  Marie-Louise Bruner Central binomial coefficients also count (2431,4231,1432,4132)-avoiders , 2015 .

[8]  R. Duncan Luce,et al.  Individual Choice Behavior , 1959 .

[9]  William V. Gehrlein,et al.  The expected probability of Condorcet's paradox , 1981 .

[10]  Amartya Sen,et al.  A Possibility Theorem on Majority Decisions , 1966 .

[11]  Guy Kindler,et al.  The geometry of manipulation — A quantitative proof of the Gibbard-Satterthwaite theorem , 2009, 2010 IEEE 51st Annual Symposium on Foundations of Computer Science.

[12]  W. Gehrlein Condorcet's paradox , 1983 .

[13]  Arkadii M. Slinko How the size of a coalition affects its chances to influence an election , 2006, Soc. Choice Welf..

[14]  Gerhard J. Woeginger,et al.  A characterization of the single-crossing domain , 2013, Soc. Choice Welf..

[15]  Mike D. Atkinson,et al.  Restricted permutations , 1999, Discret. Math..

[16]  Guy Kindler,et al.  The Geometry of Manipulation: A Quantitative Proof of the Gibbard-Satterthwaite Theorem , 2010, 2010 IEEE 51st Annual Symposium on Foundations of Computer Science.

[17]  Rolf Niedermeier,et al.  Theoretical and empirical evaluation of data reduction for exact Kemeny Rank Aggregation , 2014, Autonomous Agents and Multi-Agent Systems.

[18]  Piotr Faliszewski,et al.  The complexity of manipulative attacks in nearly single-peaked electorates , 2014, Artif. Intell..

[19]  Arkadii M. Slinko,et al.  On asymptotic strategy-proofness of the plurality and the run-off rules , 2002, Soc. Choice Welf..

[20]  Salvador Barberà,et al.  Author's Personal Copy Games and Economic Behavior Top Monotonicity: a Common Root for Single Peakedness, Single Crossing and the Median Voter Result , 2022 .

[21]  Edith Elkind,et al.  On Detecting Nearly Structured Preference Profiles , 2014, AAAI.

[22]  D. Black On the Rationale of Group Decision-making , 1948, Journal of Political Economy.

[23]  Piotr Faliszewski,et al.  The complexity of manipulative attacks in nearly single-peaked electorates , 2011, TARK XIII.

[24]  A. Gibbard Manipulation of Voting Schemes: A General Result , 1973 .

[25]  Toby Walsh,et al.  Uncertainty in Preference Elicitation and Aggregation , 2007, AAAI.

[26]  Noam Nisan,et al.  Elections Can be Manipulated Often , 2008, 2008 49th Annual IEEE Symposium on Foundations of Computer Science.

[27]  C. L. Mallows NON-NULL RANKING MODELS. I , 1957 .

[28]  Kirk Pruhs,et al.  The one-dimensional Euclidean domain: finitely many obstructions are not enough , 2015, Soc. Choice Welf..

[29]  Gerhard J. Woeginger,et al.  Are there any nicely structured preference profiles nearby? , 2013, Math. Soc. Sci..

[30]  M. Bona A new record for 1324-avoiding permutations , 2014 .

[31]  Ken-ichi Inada THE SIMPLE MAJORITY DECISION RULE , 1969 .

[32]  Norman L. Johnson,et al.  Urn models and their application , 1977 .

[33]  M. Satterthwaite Strategy-proofness and Arrow's conditions: Existence and correspondence theorems for voting procedures and social welfare functions , 1975 .

[34]  Gabrielle Demange,et al.  Single-peaked orders on a tree , 1982, Math. Soc. Sci..

[35]  Nadja Betzler,et al.  On the Computation of Fully Proportional Representation , 2011, J. Artif. Intell. Res..

[36]  Joseph S. Verducci,et al.  Probability models on rankings. , 1991 .

[37]  Tatiana Kern Bertschinger,et al.  Quality and Quantity , 1966, Nature.

[38]  Dominique Lepelley,et al.  Voting Rules, Manipulability and Social Homogeneity , 2003 .

[39]  Jérôme Lang,et al.  Single-peaked consistency and its complexity , 2008, ECAI.

[40]  Piotr Faliszewski,et al.  Clone structures in voters' preferences , 2011, EC '12.

[41]  Piotr Faliszewski,et al.  The shield that never was: Societies with single-peaked preferences are more open to manipulation and control , 2011, Inf. Comput..

[42]  Olivier Guibert Combinatoire des permutations à motifs exclus en liaison avec mots, cartes planaires et tableaux de Young , 1995 .

[43]  Toby Walsh,et al.  An Empirical Study of the Manipulability of Single Transferable Voting , 2010, ECAI.

[44]  W. Gehrlein Condorcet's paradox and the likelihood of its occurrence: different perspectives on balanced preferences* , 2002 .

[45]  Julian West,et al.  Generating trees and the Catalan and Schröder numbers , 1995, Discret. Math..

[46]  William V. Gehrlein,et al.  Voters’ preference diversity, concepts of agreement and Condorcet’s paradox , 2015 .

[47]  Hosam M. Mahmoud,et al.  Polya Urn Models , 2008 .

[48]  Arkadii Slinko,et al.  On Asymptotic Strategy-Proofness of Classical Social Choice Rules , 2002 .

[49]  Gábor Tardos,et al.  Excluded permutation matrices and the Stanley-Wilf conjecture , 2004, J. Comb. Theory, Ser. A.

[50]  Dominique Lepelley,et al.  Borda rule, Copeland method and strategic manipulation , 2002 .

[51]  R. Plackett The Analysis of Permutations , 1975 .

[52]  Craig Boutilier,et al.  Robust Winners and Winner Determination Policies under Candidate Uncertainty , 2014, AAAI.

[53]  Eddy Pariguan,et al.  On hypergeometric functions and Pochhammer -symbol. , 2004 .

[54]  Olivier Spanjaard,et al.  Bounded Single-Peaked Width and Proportional Representation , 2012, ECAI.

[55]  K. Arrow A Difficulty in the Concept of Social Welfare , 1950, Journal of Political Economy.

[56]  Miklós Bóna,et al.  Combinatorics of permutations , 2022, SIGA.

[57]  Kevin Roberts,et al.  Voting over income tax schedules , 1977 .

[58]  S. Berg Paradox of voting under an urn model: The effect of homogeneity , 1985 .

[59]  C. Coombs A theory of data. , 1965, Psychology Review.

[60]  Guillaume Haeringer,et al.  A characterization of the single-peaked domain , 2011, Soc. Choice Welf..

[61]  Edith Hemaspaandra,et al.  Bypassing Combinatorial Protections: Polynomial-Time Algorithms for Single-Peaked Electorates , 2010, AAAI.

[62]  Vicki Knoblauch,et al.  Recognizing one-dimensional Euclidean preference profiles , 2010 .

[63]  Thomas Brendan Murphy,et al.  Mixtures of distance-based models for ranking data , 2003, Comput. Stat. Data Anal..

[64]  P. Pattanaik,et al.  Necessary and Sufficient Conditions for Rational Choice under Majority Decision , 1969 .

[65]  Toby Walsh,et al.  Where are the hard manipulation problems? , 2010, J. Artif. Intell. Res..

[66]  Piotr Faliszewski,et al.  The shield that never was: societies with single-peaked preferences are more open to manipulation and control , 2009, TARK '09.