A Cognitive Hierarchy Model of Games

Players in a game are "in equilibrium" if they are rational, and accurately predict other players' strategies. In many experiments, however, players are not in equilibrium. An alternative is "cognitive hierarchy" (CH) theory, where each player assumes that his strategy is the most sophisticated. The CH model has inductively defined strategic categories: step 0 players randomize; and step k thinkers best-respond, assuming that other players are distributed over step 0 through step k - 1. This model fits empirical data, and explains why equilibrium theory predicts behavior well in some games and poorly in others. An average of 1.5 steps fits data from many games.

[1]  George Gamow,et al.  One, Two, Three...Infinity: Facts and Speculations of Science , 1947 .

[2]  T. Schelling,et al.  The Strategy of Conflict. , 1961 .

[3]  D M Messick,et al.  Interdependent decision strategies in zero-sum games: a computer-controlled study. , 1967, Behavioral science.

[4]  Nancy L. Stokey,et al.  Information, Trade, and Common Knowledge , 1982 .

[5]  B. O'Neill Nonmetric test of the minimax theory of two-person zerosum games. , 1987, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America.

[6]  Ken Binmore,et al.  Modeling Rational Players: Part II , 1987, Economics and Philosophy.

[7]  Daniel Kahneman,et al.  EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS: A PSYCHOLOGICAL PERSPECTIVE , 1988 .

[8]  Reinhard Selten,et al.  Bounded rational behavior in experimental games and markets : proceedings of the Fourth Conference on Experimental Economics, Bielefeld, West Germany, September 21-25, 1986 , 1988 .

[9]  John C. Harsanyi,et al.  Общая теория выбора равновесия в играх / A General Theory of Equilibrium Selection in Games , 1989 .

[10]  Robert W. Rosenthal,et al.  A bounded-rationality approach to the study of noncooperative games , 1989 .

[11]  J. Huyck,et al.  Tacit Coordination Games, Strategic Uncertainty, and Coordination Failure , 1990 .

[12]  A. Rapoport,et al.  Mixed strategies in strictly competitive games: A further test of the minimax hypothesis , 1992 .

[13]  R. Bloomfield Learning a mixed strategy equilibrium in the laboratory , 1994 .

[14]  J. Banks,et al.  An Experimental Analysis of Nash Refinements in Signaling Games , 1994 .

[15]  D. Stahl,et al.  On Players' Models of Other Players: Theory and Experimental Evidence , 1995 .

[16]  J. Ochs Games with Unique, Mixed Strategy Equilibria: An Experimental Study , 1995 .

[17]  R. McKelvey,et al.  Quantal Response Equilibria for Normal Form Games , 1995 .

[18]  Teck-Hua Ho,et al.  Task complexity, equilibrium selection, and learning: an experimental study , 1996 .

[19]  Dilip Mookherjee,et al.  Learning and Decision Costs in Experimental Constant Sum Games , 1997 .

[20]  R. Selten Features of experimentally observed bounded rationality , 1998 .

[21]  D. Stahl Is step-j thinking an arbitrary modelling restriction or a fact of human nature? , 1998 .

[22]  R. McKelvey,et al.  Quantal Response Equilibria for Extensive Form Games , 1998 .

[23]  Colin Camerer,et al.  Iterated Dominance and Iterated Best-Response in Experimental P-Beauty Contests , 1998 .

[24]  Colin Camerer,et al.  Overconfidence and Excess Entry: An Experimental Approach , 1999 .

[25]  Miguel A. Costa-Gomes,et al.  Cognition and Behavior in Normal-Form Games: An Experimental Study , 1998 .

[26]  R. Cooper,et al.  Coordination games : complementarities and macroeconomics , 1999 .

[27]  Rosemarie Nagel,et al.  One, Two, (Three), Infinity: Newspaper and Lab Beauty-Contest Experiments , 2000 .

[28]  Colin F. Camerer,et al.  Strategic Learning and Teaching , 2000 .

[29]  David I. Laibson,et al.  A Boundedly Rational Decision Algorithm , 2000 .

[30]  A. Rapoport,et al.  Mixed strategies and iterative elimination of strongly dominated strategies: an experimental investi , 2000 .

[31]  Eld,et al.  Cursed Equilibrium , 2000 .

[32]  K. Binmore,et al.  Does Minimax Work? An Experimental Study , 2001 .

[33]  Fang-Fang Tang,et al.  Anticipatory learning in two-person games: some experimental results , 2001 .

[34]  Georg Weizsäcker Ignoring the Rationality of Others: Evidence from Experimental Normal-form Games , 2001 .

[35]  T. Hedden,et al.  What do you think I think you think?: Strategic reasoning in matrix games , 2002, Cognition.

[36]  Colin Camerer Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction , 2003 .

[37]  Stephanie Kovalchika,et al.  AGING AND DECISION MAKING : A BROAD COMPARATIVE STUDY OF DECISION BEHAVIOR IN NEUROLOGICALLY HEALTHY ELDERLY AND YOUNG INDIVIDUALS , 2003 .

[38]  Miguel A. Costa-Gomes,et al.  Cognition and Behavior in Two-Person Guessing Games: An Experimental Study , 2003 .

[39]  D. Kahneman Maps of Bounded Rationality: Psychology for Behavioral Economics , 2003 .

[40]  Georg Weizsäcker,et al.  Ignoring the rationality of others: evidence from experimental normal-form games , 2003, Games Econ. Behav..

[41]  David J. Cooper,et al.  Evidence on the equivalence of the strategic and extensive form representation of games , 2003, J. Econ. Theory.

[42]  Jean-Robert Tyran,et al.  Limited Rationality and Strategic Interaction - the Impact of the Strategic Environment on Nominal Inertia , 2007 .

[43]  Colin Camerer,et al.  A cognitive hierarchy theory of one-shot games: Some preliminary results , 2003 .

[44]  David Laibson,et al.  The Allocation of Attention: Theory and Evidence , 2003 .

[45]  Massimo Warglien,et al.  Games and phone numbers: Do short-term memory bounds affect strategic behavior? , 2003 .

[46]  Teck-Hua Ho,et al.  A Cognitive Hierarchy Theory of One-shot Games and Experimental Analysis , 2003 .

[47]  V. Crawford Lying for Strategic Advantage: Rational and Boundedly Rational Misrepresentation of Intentions , 2003 .

[48]  Colin Camerer,et al.  Neuroeconomics: Why Economics Needs Brains , 2004 .

[49]  Colin Camerer,et al.  Aging and decision making: a comparison between neurologically healthy elderly and young individuals , 2005 .