Multiple Good Valuation

Assume for the moment that you are the supervisor of the Roosevelt National Forest (it’s located near our town of Fort Collins, Colorado). You have been asked by the Chief of the Forest Service how you would spend a specified increase in your budget. You could spend the increase on such projects as improved campgrounds, better roads for reaching the backcountry, reduction in forest fuels to lower the risk of wildfire, and watershed management to lower erosion and thereby improve fish habitat. You know your chances of getting an increase depend on how well you support your proposal. You can design options that use up the budget increase, but you don’t have good information about the benefits of, or even the public preferences for, the options. You know what the vocal interest groups want, but you would like your proposal to have some quantitative justification that reflects the values of the wider citizenry who care about the National Forest. You examined the economic analyses that had been done about forest resources in the area and found no studies for most of the major resources you manage. You don’t have time for separate valuation studies of each of the options. However, you could commission a single study directly comparing the values people place on the options-a multiple good valuation study. Furthermore, because the options cost the same amount, a preference ordering of the options is all you need to choose the best one. That option might then become the focus of an economic valuation study, which would allow a benefit-cost comparison.1

[1]  Eric J. Johnson,et al.  Behavioral decision research: A constructive processing perspective. , 1992 .

[2]  Gregory J. Buhyoff,et al.  Estimating psychological disutility from damaged forest stands. , 1978 .

[3]  J. Knetsch,et al.  Coastal Management Using Public Judgments, Importance Scales, and Predetermined Schedule , 2001 .

[4]  D. McFadden Conditional logit analysis of qualitative choice behavior , 1972 .

[5]  Daniel Kahneman,et al.  Referendum contingent valuation, anchoring, and willingness to pay for public goods , 1998 .

[6]  T. Brown,et al.  Economic Valuation by the Method of Paired Comparison, with Emphasis on Evaluation of the Transitivity Axiom , 1998 .

[7]  T. Brown,et al.  Environmental Damage Schedules: Community Judgments of Importance and Assessments of Losses , 2001, Land Economics.

[8]  H. A. David,et al.  The method of paired comparisons , 1966 .

[9]  Moshe Ben-Akiva,et al.  Discrete Choice Analysis: Theory and Application to Travel Demand , 1985 .

[10]  P. Slovic The Construction of Preference , 1995 .

[11]  G. Fechner Elemente der Psychophysik , 1998 .

[12]  A. Tversky,et al.  Contingent weighting in judgment and choice , 1988 .

[13]  G. Peterson Children's Choice of Playground Equipment: Development of Methodology for Integrating User Preferences into Environmental Engineering. , 1973 .

[14]  William S. Breffle,et al.  Comparing Choice Question Formats for Evaluating Natural Resource Tradeoffs , 2002, Land Economics.

[15]  L. Thurstone The method of paired comparisons for social values , 1927 .

[16]  T. Ll Psychophysical analysis. By L. L. Thurstone, 1927. , 1987 .

[17]  K. Boyle,et al.  Anchoring and Adjustment in Single-Bounded, Contingent-Valuation Questions , 1997 .

[18]  Thomas C. Brown,et al.  Judged seriousness of environmental losses: reliability and cause of loss , 2002 .

[19]  J. Knetsch The Endowment Effect and Evidence of Nonreversible Indifference Curves. , 1989 .

[20]  M. Kendall,et al.  ON THE METHOD OF PAIRED COMPARISONS , 1940 .

[21]  L. Thurstone A law of comparative judgment. , 1994 .

[22]  R. Ferber Handbook of Marketing Research , 1974 .

[23]  Joseph L. Zinnes,et al.  Theory and Methods of Scaling. , 1958 .