The Design of Durable Goods

The use of a durable good is limited by both its physical life and usable life. For example, an electric-car battery can last for five years (physical life) or 100,000 miles (usable life), whichever comes first. We propose a framework for examining how a profit-maximizing firm might choose the usable life, physical life, and selling price of a durable good. The proposed framework considers differences in usage rates and product valuations by consumers and allows for the effects of technological constraints and product obsolescence on a product's usable and physical lives. Our main result characterizes a relationship between optimal price, cost elasticities, and opportunity costs associated with relaxing upper bounds on usable and physical lives. We describe conditions under which either usable life or physical life, or both, obtains its maximum possible values; examine why a firm might devote effort to relaxing nonbinding constraints on usable life or physical life; consider when price cuts might be accompanied with product improvements; and examine how a firm might be able to cross-subsidize product improvements.

[1]  E. Kleiman,et al.  The Durability of Durable Goods , 1966 .

[2]  I. Png,et al.  Market segmentation, cannibalization, and the timing of product introductions , 1992 .

[3]  Daniel A. Levinthal,et al.  Durable Goods and Product Obsolescence , 1989 .

[4]  Durability of Consumption Goods Reconsidered , 1975 .

[5]  Ramesh Krishnamurti,et al.  A Heuristic Approach to Product Design , 1987 .

[6]  Oded Koenigsberg,et al.  Research Note - The Role of Production Lead Time and Demand Uncertainty in Marketing Durable Goods , 2007, Manag. Sci..

[7]  F. Bass A new product growth model for consumer durables , 1976 .

[8]  Paul E. Green,et al.  Models and Heuristics for Product Line Selection , 1985 .

[9]  D. Levhari,et al.  Durability of Consumption Goods: Competition Versus Monopoly , 1969 .

[10]  Product Durability under Monopoly and Competition: Comment , 1977 .

[11]  Preyas S. Desai Leasing and Selling: Optimal Marketing Strategies for a Durable Goods Firm (Лизинг и продажи: оптимальные маркетинговые стратегии для изготовителя товаров длительного пользования) , 1998 .

[12]  R. Shankar,et al.  Innovation and the Durable Goods Monopolist: The Optimality of Frequent New-Version Releases , 2007 .

[13]  Market Organization and the Durability of Durable Goods , 1977 .

[14]  Optimal dynamic durability , 1990 .

[15]  Vijay Mahajan,et al.  New Product Diffusion Models in Marketing: A Review and Directions for Research: , 1990 .

[16]  J Thölke,et al.  Launching new product features: a multiple case examination , 2001 .

[17]  Robert M. Freund,et al.  Optimizing Product Line Designs: Efficient Methods and Comparisons , 2008, Manag. Sci..

[18]  M. Kamien,et al.  Product Durability under Monopoly and Competition , 1974 .

[19]  R. Barro Monopoly and Contrived Depreciation , 1972, Journal of Political Economy.

[20]  E. Sieper,et al.  Monopoly and Competition in the Market for Durable Goods , 1973 .

[21]  P. Swan Durability of Consumption Goods , 1970 .

[22]  Preyas S. Desai,et al.  Competition in Durable Goods Markets: The Strategic Consequences of Leasing and Selling , 1999 .

[23]  Richard Schmalensee,et al.  Market Structure, Durability, and Maintenance Effort , 1974 .

[24]  Richard Schmalensee Regulation and the durability of goods , 1970 .

[25]  Frank M. Bass,et al.  A New Product Growth for Model Consumer Durables , 2004, Manag. Sci..

[26]  Eitan Muller,et al.  The dynamic adjustment of optimal durability and quality , 1988 .

[27]  Richard Schmalensee,et al.  Market Structure, Durability, and Quality: A Selective Survey , 1979 .