Human capital and the rise of American cities, 1900–1990

Abstract We propose that cities that start out with proportionately more knowledgeable people grow faster in the long run because (a) knowledge spillovers are geographically limited to the city and (b) much knowledge is most productive in the city within which it is acquired. We found that city-aggregates and metropolitan areas with higher average levels of human capital grew faster over the 20th century. The estimated effects of human capital were large: a standard deviation increase in human capital in 1900 was associated with a 38% increase in average annual employment growth of city-aggregates over the period 1900–86. The estimated effects for metropolitan areas were smaller but still economically significant: a standard deviation increase in 1940 human capital was associated with an increase in average annual employment growth over the period 1940–90 of about 15%. Although the rise of the automobile appears to have overwhelmed the importance of human capital in cities dominated by manufacturing early on, human capital seems to have been economically more important in manufacturing cities than in non-manufacturing cities later on. Moreover, the estimated effects of human capital persisted for very long periods of time, suggesting either that adjusting to the steady state is very lengthy, or that shocks to growth are correlated with the presence of human capital.

[1]  F. Y. Edgeworth,et al.  Adna Ferrin Weber. The Growth of Cities in the Nineteenth Century. A Study in Statistics , 1899 .

[2]  W. H. Phillips Patent Growth in the Old Dominion: The Impact of Railroad Integration before 1880 , 1992, The Journal of Economic History.

[3]  L. Davis American economic growth : an economist's history of the United States , 1974 .

[4]  James E. Rauch Bureaucracy, Infrastructure, and Economic Growth: Evidence from U.S. Cities During the Progressive Era , 1994 .

[5]  J. Henderson,et al.  Externalities and Industrial Development , 1994 .

[6]  Charlotte Erickson,et al.  Railroads And American Economic Growth , 1964 .

[7]  P. Krugman Increasing Returns and Economic Geography , 1991 .

[8]  Douglass C. North,et al.  Location Theory and Regional Economic Growth , 1955, Journal of Political Economy.

[9]  Product differentiation and economic growth in a system of cities , 1994 .

[10]  Ari Kuncoro,et al.  Industrial Development in Cities , 1992, Journal of Political Economy.

[11]  Harry W. Richardson,et al.  The economics of urban size , 1973 .

[12]  Stanley Lebergott,et al.  The Americans: An Economic Record. , 1985 .

[13]  Peter B. Doeringer,et al.  Explaining variations in employment growth: Structural and cyclical change among states and local areas , 1991 .

[14]  A. Schlesinger The Rise of the City, 1878-1898 , 1999 .

[15]  H. Abdel-Rahman Product differentiation, monopolistic competition and city size , 1988 .

[16]  Lawrence F. Katz,et al.  The Origins of Technology-Skill Complementarity , 1996 .

[17]  Curtis J. Simon,et al.  Human Capital and Metropolitan Employment Growth , 1998 .

[18]  Duncan Black,et al.  A Theory of Urban Growth , 1999, Journal of Political Economy.

[19]  D. Worcester,et al.  A history of Florida , 1971 .

[20]  Charles M. Tiebout Exports and Regional Economic Growth: Rejoinder , 1956, Journal of Political Economy.

[21]  R. Lucas On the Mechanics of Economic Development , 1988 .

[22]  F. Rivera-batiz,et al.  Increasing returns, monopolistic competition, and agglomeration economies in consumption and production , 1988 .

[23]  The reinterpretation of American economic history , 1972 .

[24]  Zvi Eckstein,et al.  Cities and Growth: Theory and Evidence from France and Japan , 1994 .

[25]  Andrei Shleifer,et al.  Economic Growth in a Cross-Section of Cities , 1995 .

[26]  Charles M. Tiebout Exports and Regional Economic Growth , 1956, Journal of Political Economy.

[27]  M. Feldman,et al.  R&D spillovers and the ge-ography of innovation and production , 1996 .

[28]  Kenneth L. Sokoloff,et al.  Inventive Activity in Early Industrial America: Evidence From Patent Records, 1790–1846 , 1988, The Journal of Economic History.

[29]  Anthony H. Pascal,et al.  The Economic Transformation of American Cities , 1984 .

[30]  E. Glaeser,et al.  Growth in Cities , 1991, Journal of Political Economy.

[31]  W. Smith The Function of Commercial Centers in the Modernization of European Capitalism: Amsterdam as an Information Exchange in the Seventeenth Century , 1984, The Journal of Economic History.

[32]  L. Vogel,et al.  Strategy and Structure , 1986 .

[33]  Curtis J. Simon,et al.  The Talk of the Town: Human Capital, Information, and the Growth of English Cities, 1861 to 1961 , 1996 .

[34]  James E. Rauch,et al.  Productivity Gains from Geographic Concentration of Human Capital: Evidence from the Cities , 1991 .

[35]  Joshua S. Gans,et al.  Urban Productivity and Factor Growth in the Late Nineteenth Century , 1995 .

[36]  Edward L. Glaeser,et al.  Information Technology and the Future of Cities , 1996 .

[37]  C. N. Glaab,et al.  A history of urban America , 1967 .

[38]  L. Cain William Dean' Theory of Urban Growth: Chicago's Commerce and Industry, 1854–1871 , 1985, The Journal of Economic History.

[39]  Theodore Palivos,et al.  Spatial agglomeration and endogenous growth , 1996 .

[40]  L. Galambos,et al.  The transformation of the American economy, 1865-1914 , 1971 .

[41]  Masahisa Fujita,et al.  PRODUCT VARIETY, MARSHALLIAN EXTERNALITIES, AND CITY SIZES , 1990 .